Revised Draft
October 6, 2003
BASEL II: THE ROAR THAT
MOUSED
George G. Kaufman*
(Loyola University Chicago
and Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago)
In 1999, the Basel Committee on Banking
Supervision issued a consultative paper describing proposed
modifications to the capital standards for commercial banks, which had
first been introduced by the Committee in 1988 and implemented in many
industrial countries starting in 1991 (Basel Committee, 2003a). The new
proposal became known as Basel II to differentiate it from the earlier
Basel I. To a large extent, the proposed Basel II was in response to
widespread criticism of Basel I. But it also reflected additional
thought and analysis of the role of bank capital regulation. In
particular, Basel II added two new “pillars” – supervisory review
(pillar 2) and market discipline (pillar 3) -- to the single pillar of
minimum capital requirement of Basel I. In response to public comments,
the Committee revised its proposal twice and issued a third consultative
paper (CP3) in early 2003. If approved, the proposed standards are
scheduled for implementation in most countries at the beginning of 2007.
In preparation, in August 2003, U.S. regulators circulated an Advance
Notice of Proposed Rulemaking (ANPR) for the application of Basel II to
U.S. banks for public comment by November and the major features have
been incorporated by the European Union in a proposed revision of its
Capital Adequacy Directive (CAD) for financial institutions, which must,
however, be approved by the European Parliament and the member national
parliaments before adoption.
This paper focuses on the proposed two
new pillars, which have received far less attention than the capital
standards pillar. The paper concludes that both pillars have major
design flaws that make achievement of the capital requirements
determined by pillar 1, regardless of their desirability, questionable.
These flaws help to explain both the recent decision of the U.S. bank
regulators to limit the mandatory application of Basel II to only the
ten or so largest internationally active U.S. banks and why these
requirements may be ineffective even for these banks. Thus, although
Basel II roared loudly when proposed, it is likely to have only a
relatively minor lasting effect on the capital of, at least, most U.S.
banks.
II. Overview of Basel and Pillar 1
The Basel Committee on Banking
Supervision was established in 1974 by a number of western industrial
countries (G-10), primarily in response to the failure of the Herstatt
Bank in Germany that had significant adverse implications for both
foreign exchange markets and banks in other countries.1 The
Committee focused on facilitating and enhancing information sharing and
cooperation among bank regulators in major countries and developing
principles for the supervision of internationally active large banks
(Herring and Litan, 1995). As losses at some large international banks
from loans to less-developed countries (LDCs) mounted in the late-1970s,
the Committee became increasingly concerned that the potential failures
of one or more of these banks could have serious adverse effects not
only for the other banks in their own countries, but also for
counterparty banks in other countries, i.e., cross-border contagion. The
Committee feared that large banks lacked sufficient capital in relation
to the risks they were assuming and that the inadequacy in large part
reflected the reluctance of national governments to require higher
capital ratios for fear of putting their own banks at a competitive
disadvantage relative to banks in other countries.
In the 1980s, this concern was
particularly directed at Japanese banks, which were rapidly expanding
globally based on valuations of capital that included large amounts of
unrealized capital gains from rapid increases in the values of Japanese
stocks that they owned. Such gains were not included in the capital
valuations permitted banks in most other countries, where equity
ownership by banks was more restrictive. Partially as a result, the
Committee began to focus more on developing international regulation
that centered on higher and more uniform bank capital standards across
countries. The capital standards developed and introduced in 1988 became
known as Basel I.
Perhaps the most revolutionary aspect of
the capital requirements developed in Basel I was relating a bank’s
capital to the perceived credit risk of the bank’s portfolio. Before
that, most regulators focused on simple leverage ratios that used only
total assets as the base. Basel I also incorporated off-balance sheet
assets in the base as well as on-balance sheet assets and weighted
individual assets by a risk factor. However, the formula constructed was
a relatively simple one that treated all banks equally -- one size fits
all. Individual assets were divided into four basic credit risk
categories or buckets according to the identity of their counterparty
and assigned weights ranging from 0 to 100 percent. The weighted values
of the individual on- and off- balance sheet assets were then summed and
classified as “risk-weighted assets.” Banks were required to maintain
capital of not less than 8 percent of their risk-weighted assets. This
capital ratio is referred to as risk-based capital (RBC).
But the arbitrary nature of both the risk
classes and risk weights led to widespread criticism that the resulting
risk-based capital requirements were neither realistic nor useful and to
“gaming” by the banks as they exploited differences in returns computed
on different assets on the basis of the regulator assigned capital
requirements -- regulatory capital -- vis-à-vis that perceived to be
required by market forces -- economic capital. Such arbitrage likely
results in misallocation of resources and reduced economic and social
welfare. In addition, total bank credit risk was measured as the sum of
the credit risks of the individual asset components, giving no weight to
any gains from diversification across less than perfectly correlated
assets. Nevertheless, the capital requirements established by Basel 1
were implemented by an increasing number of countries, including the
United States, starting in 1991 and became the effective capital
standards for banks worldwide.
Shortly thereafter, in response to the
criticisms of its formula and the avoidance activities of banks, the
Basel Committee began to work on improving the capital requirements. The
structure of the credit risk weights was modified and their values were
determined by three alternative methods, depending on the size and
financial sophistication of the bank. In addition, explicit weights were
assigned to operational risk and the Basel I weights maintained for
market and trading risk.
With respect to credit risk exposure, the
most important risk component in the Basel structure, potential losses
from default are effectively divided into two components -- 1) the
probability of default (PD) and 2) the loss given default (LGD).2
The values for these measures are to be stipulated by the regulators for
the smaller, least sophisticated banks and progressively shifted to the
banks as their sophistication increases. The smallest, least
sophisticated banks are permitted to apply the “standardized approach”
to compute their risk weighted assets. Weights are assigned by the
regulators for individual assets, based to a large extent on credit
ratings that the bank’s counterparties have received from private credit
rating agencies on their outstanding marketable debt that implicitly
reflect both PD and LGD.3 The standardized approach resembles
Basel I, but is somewhat more complex. Bank assets are divided into five
rather than four basic groupings and the risk-weights for each group are
both based more on market evidence and stretch over a wider range. But
otherwise, the same criticisms that were directed at Basel I may also be
directed at this approach in Basel II. On the other hand, the
standardized approach has the virtue of simplicity and, as it applies
only to small banks, its failings may not be very costly in terms of any
lasting damage to the domestic or international financial markets as a
whole.
Larger banks are to rely more on
internally generated information -- the internal ratings approach (IRB)
-- in which PD and LGD are explicit. Most would compute their own PD for
individual loans, but use values for LGD provided by the regulators.
This is referred to as the “foundation IRB approach.” The largest and
most sophisticated banks may use the “advanced IRB approach” (A-IRB),
which permits them to determine their own values for both PD and LGD.
The models used by the banks to obtain their values need to be evaluated
and preapproved by the regulators.
Although the IRB approaches overcome some
of the criticism of the Basel I bucket approach, they are not devoid of
criticism. In particular, the loss rates determined by the regulators
are subject to large errors so that gaming is still likely and the
models used by the banks to generate their internal values are likely to
be too complex and opaque for supervisors (and even many bankers
themselves) to understand thoroughly, so that the resulting capital
amounts will be difficult to evaluate for adequacy and compliance with
the requirements. The description of the proposed regulations for the
application of A-IRB to large U.S. banks in the ANPR takes more than 30
small type, three column pages in the Federal Register (Federal
Register, 2003). As has been frequently noted, although the real
world is complex, complexity per se does not necessarily achieve
reality.
The discussion of pillar 1 also bypasses
a number of important issues concerning the definition and measurement
of capital, in particular, what is capital; is dividing capital into
tiers appropriate and, if so, what should be the criteria; role of “subdebt;”
what is the relationship between capital and loan loss reserves; and how
should loss reserves be determined over the business cycle (Shadow
Financial Regulatory Committee, 2000; Laeven and Majnoni, 2003; and
Borio, Furfine, and Lowe, 2001). Failure to consider these issues
greatly weakens the usefulness of the recommendations.
Many of the above criticisms of pillar 1
and, in particular, of regulator- rather than market-determined RBC have
been made by many parties. The remainder of this paper will focus on
pillars 2 and 3, which are intended both to effectively enforce and to
supplement the capital requirements determined in pillar 1 and have
received far less attention.
III. Supervisory Review (Pillar 2)
Supervisory review “is intended… to
ensure that banks have adequate capital to support all the risks in
their business” (Basel, 2003, p. 138) determined both by pillar 1 and by
supervisory evaluation of risks not explicitly captured in pillar 1,
e.g., interest rate risk and credit concentration. “Supervisors are
expected to evaluate how well banks are assessing their capital needs
relative to their risks and to intervene, where appropriate. This
interaction is intended to foster an active dialogue between banks and
supervisors such that when deficiencies are identified, prompt and
decisive action can be taken to reduce risk or restore capital” (Basel,
2003, p. 138). This supervisory responsibility is spelled out further in
three of four key principles developed for supervisory review.
Principle 2 of pillar 2 states that
“supervisors should take appropriate supervisory action if they are not
satisfied with” (Basel, 2003, p. 142) their review and evaluation of the
adequacy of the banks’ internal models. Moreover, principle 3 states
that “supervisors should expect banks to operate above the minimum
regulatory capital ratios and should have the ability to require banks
to hold capital in excess of the minimum” (Basel, 2003, p. 144).
Principle 4 states that “supervisors should seek to intervene at an
early stage to prevent capital from falling below the minimum levels…
and should require rapid remedial action if capital is not maintained or
restored” (Basel, 2003, p. 144). But nowhere in CP3 are supervisors
granted the tools and authority to perform these functions. This makes
it less likely that countries not currently granting regulators such
powers will introduce them when adopting Basel II.
In contrast, in the U.S., the FDIC
Improvement Act (FDICIA) enacted at yearend 1991, the same year as Basel
I was implemented in the U.S., not only explicitly granted supervisors
the authority to impose such sanctions on banks that failed to maintain
minimum capital requirements but required the regulators to impose such
sanctions when the capital ratios of banks declined below given
threshold levels or the banks displayed other indications of financial
troubles. The system of first discretionary and then mandatory
regulatory sanctions in FDICIA is referred to as prompt corrective
action (PCA). FDICIA specifies that both RBC and simple capital leverage
ratios need to be considered and the bank regulators defined RBC in
accord with Basel I. Banks have to satisfy all three capital measures
specified. The mandatory sanctions were included to supplement the
discretionary sanctions because the U.S. experience with the banking and
thrift crises of the 1980s suggested that for a number of reasons
regulators may not always intervene in troubled institutions in a
forceful and timely fashion and instead delay or forbear (Benston and
Kaufman, 1994 and Kaufman, 1995).
The structure of discretionary and
mandatory sanctions included in PCA is summarized in Table 1. Both sets
of sanctions are designed to become progressively harsher and the
mandatory sanctions progressively more important as the financial
condition of a bank deteriorates and its capital ratios decline below
the thresholds of each of the five capital tranches or tripwires. The
mandatory sanctions are to protect against undue delay and forbearance
by regulators in imposing discretionary sanctions (Benston and Kaufman,
1994). The sanctions mimic those that the market typically imposes on
unregulated firms facing similar financial difficulties. Shortly after a
bank becomes “critically undercapitalized,” which is currently defined
as a 2 percent equity to asset ratio, the regulators are required to
place the institution in receivership or conservatorship (legal closure)
and to resolve it at least cost to the FDIC.
The purpose of the sanctions is not to
punish the bank per se, but to provide incentives for owners and
managers to turn the bank around and return it to greater profitability
and a stronger capital position. Without similar PCA type authority, it
is unlikely that bank regulators in other countries can achieve the
control over a bank’s capital that pillar 2 envisions. Indeed, the early
experience with PCA in the U.S. suggests that some regulators may not be
using their authority as vigorously as intended in the legislation and
that supervisory review needs to be supplemented by other forces
including market discipline, which is pillar 3 in the Basel II proposal
(Kaufman, 2003b).
III. Market Discipline (Pillar 3)
Market discipline may be defined as
actions by stakeholders to both monitor and influence the behavior of
entities to improve their performance (Bliss and Flannery, 2002). Pillar
3 in Basel II is intended “to complement the minimum capital
requirements (Pillar 1) and the supervisory review process (Pillar 2) …
[and] to encourage market discipline by developing a set of disclosure
requirements which will allow market participants to assess… the capital
adequacy of the institution” (Basel, 2003, p. 154). Unfortunately, the
requirements for effective market discipline are not discussed in the
section on market discipline in CP3. Rather, the section discusses in
great detail what information on a bank’s financial and risk positions
need be disclosed to the public (Lopez, 2003).
But disclosure and transparency is a
necessary but not sufficient condition for effective market discipline.
What is required is, at least, some at-risk bank stakeholders.
Stakeholders not at-risk would have little or no incentive to monitor
and influence their banks and thus have little if any use for the
information disclosed about the financial performance of the banks.
While market discipline is likely to encourage disclosure, disclosure
per se is less likely to encourage market discipline in the absence of a
significant number of at-risk stakeholders. Because of the fear of
substantial economic harm caused by the failure of large banks,
governments and bank regulators in almost all countries have tended to
avoid failing such institutions and, where they have, protected all
depositors and other creditors in a de-facto policy termed
“too-big-to-fail” (TBTF), (Kaufman, 2003a). Thus, few de-facto at-risk
stakeholders have existed in even privately owned banks, no less state
owned banks. However, the U.S. has taken steps in recent years to
enhance market discipline by reversing the policy of blanket protection
of debt stakeholders and converting the largest stakeholders --
depositors, creditors, and shareholders -- to at-risk status. FDICIA
prohibits the FDIC from protecting any uninsured stakeholder at failed
banks in which doing so is not a least-cost resolution to it. But there
is an exception.
If there is evidence that not protecting
uninsured depositors and/or other creditors at a failed bank “would have
serious adverse effects on economic conditions or financial stability;
and … any action or assistance… would avoid or mitigate such adverse
effects” the regulators can petition the Secretary of the Treasury to
permit such protection. This provision is called the Systemic Risk
Exception (SRE) and replaces TBTF. But obtaining permission to do so is
not easy. There are a number of significant before and after hurdles
that need to be cleared. To invoke SRE, a recommendation must be made in
writing to the Secretary of the Treasury by two-thirds of both the Board
of Directors of the FDIC and the Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System that protection of at least some uninsured stakeholders
is necessary to avoid the serious adverse effects cited in the FDICIA
legislation. The Secretary must consult with the President before
agreeing with the recommendation, must retain written documentation for
review, and must, again in writing, notify the Banking Committees of
both the House of Representatives and the Senate (Kaufman, 2003a).
After any protection is provided, a
review of the need for the action taken and the consequences must be
completed by the General Accounting Office (GAO) and any losses suffered
by the FDIC in providing the assistance must be paid “expeditiously”
through a special assessment on all insured banks based on their asset
size. These barriers appear sufficiently high and difficult to clear to
make the SRE exception an exception rather than the rule as was the case
with TBTF before FDICIA and thereby increase the number of large and
assumably sophisticated at-risk stakeholders. Since 1992, no SREs have
been requested or granted and uninsured depositors and creditors have
experienced losses in all failures with resolution losses except in a
few small bank resolutions where protecting the uninsured depositors did
not increase the loss to the FDIC. In some resolutions, losses to
unprotected depositors exceeded 40 percent and other creditors even more
(Kaufman, 2003b). On the other hand, since 1992, no large money center
bank has encountered insolvency, so that the SRE has not really been
tested.
Another way to increase the importance or
at-risk claimants is to require banks to issue a minimum amount of
subordinated debt (subdebt), (Shadow Financial Regulatory Committee,
2000; Evanoff and Wall, 2002, Basel Committee, 2003b, Benston et al,
1986).4 Such debt would be both de-jure as well as credibly
de-facto unprotected and therefore at-risk. Thus, the interest yield
spreads at which it is either sold initially in the primary market or
traded later in the secondary market would reflect investors perceptions
of the financial strength of the issuing institution (Jagtiani et al.,
2002). These market determined yield spreads are likely both to affect
investors’ attitudes toward the institution and management’s actions,
and to serve as a signal to regulators of market perceptions. Such
signals would supplement the information regulators obtain from their
own examinations and other sources and in some proposals would
automatically feed into PCA and possibly trigger sanctions on the
institution when the yield spreads become sufficiently large.
Unfortunately, to date, regulators in neither the U.S. nor the other
Basel countries have viewed these proposals favorably and implemented
them.
V. Conclusions
The coming of Basel II was announced with
great fanfare and has already been incorporated in a notice of proposed
rulemaking in the U.S. and a proposed revised CAD in the EU countries.
But, particularly in the U.S., praise by the industry, regulators, and
scholars have been much more muted and have become progressively even
more muted through time as the details are examined more closely.5
Indeed, U.S. bank regulators have recently effectively rejected Basel II
as a requirement for all but the largest 10 or so internationally active
banks, which would be required to use the advanced IRB approach. All
other banks may compute their RBC on the basis of the current Basel I,
although they can adopt the advanced IRB approach if they wish and their
supervisors concur.
The rejection in the U.S. centers
primarily on the complexity of computations and doubts about the
adequacy of the RBC requirement, the inadequacies of pillars 2 and 3
analyzed in this paper, and the existence of PCA in the U.S. to which
all banks are subject. For example, Federal Reserve Vice-Chairman, Roger
Ferguson has stated that “for the United States banking authorities,
pillar II of Basel II requires nothing new… [and] considerable
information is publicly disseminated -- for example, through our Call
Reports -- and is available for counterparties” (Ferguson, June 10,
2003, p. 3). Similar views have been expressed by the Comptroller of the
Currency (Hawke, 2003a and b). That is, despite its well-recognized
shortcomings, the U.S. already has a more effective system in place.
Moreover, to the extent the advanced IRB
approach may compute lower capital requirements for the largest banks
that will use it, even after addition of operational risk, as it appears
likely to do and appears to be its major appeal, these banks are still
subject to the minimum leverage ratio constraint, which is unaffected by
Basel II. Indeed, the ANPR specifically states that “ the Agencies are
not proposing to introduce specific requirements or guidelines to
implement Pillar 2. Instead, existing guidance, rules, and regulations
would continue to be enforced” (Federal Register, 2003, p.
45905).
This paper supports much of the criticism
of proposed Basel II, particularly with respect to pillar 1. However,
regardless of the complexity or desirability of RBC computed according
to pillar 1, the provisions of pillars 2 and 3 are inadequate to enforce
them. Although pillar 2 discusses the need for supervisors to intervene
promptly if either a bank’s capital or the model used to compute capital
are perceived inadequate and impose remedial action, no powers are
explicitly recommended for supervisors to effectively enforce this
mandate. What appears necessary in countries that do not currently
provide for such powers is the introduction of a system of PCA similar
to that required in the U.S. since the enactment of FDICIA in 1991.
Pillar 3 proposes to enhance market discipline by increasing financial
disclosure requirements for banks. But disclosure is most effective if
there are substantial bank stakeholders at-risk. Presently, few
stakeholders, particularly de-jure uninsured depositors, view themselves
at-risk as regulators have tended to protect them in nearly all large
bank failures in almost all countries. What is necessary to enhance
market discipline further is to increase the number and importance of
stakeholders who perceive themselves at-risk de-facto as well as de-jure.
This requires scaling back TBTF, as has been attempted in the U.S. with
the introduction of SRE. Adoption of a subdebt requirement would
expedite this process.
Thus, on the other hand, until the
Committee proposes more substantial pillars for enhancing supervisory
review and market disciple, Basel II will encounter difficulties in
fulfilling many of the grand promises made at its introduction,
particularly outside the United States. On the other hand, however,
regardless of its shortcomings, Basel II has both increased our
knowledge of the nature and measurement of risk in banking and increased
the sensitivity of bankers, regulators, analysts, and the public to risk
management. This is no small feat in itself and may represent Basel II’s
major lasing contribution. Indeed, the Basel proposals may make their
greatest lasting contribution by continuing to be an ongoing process
that is never implemented.
__________________________________
I am indebted to
Bill Bergman, Robert Bliss, Douglas Evanoff and Richard Herring for
their helpful comments on earlier drafts of this paper. Prepared for
presentation at the annual meetings of the Financial Management
Association, Denver, October 10, 2003
1
Current members countries are Belgium,
Canada, France, Germany, Italy, Japan, Luxembourg, the Netherlands,
Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, the United Kingdom, and the United States.
2 It appears ironic that the
credit risk exposure of banks, who are widely assumed to be
beneficiaries of private information on their loan customers, is
measured by the ratings assigned to their public debt traded on the
capital market, which is widely assumed to have little if any private
information.
In addition, assets are assigned
values for maturity and exposure at default.
4 Since
the Depositor Preference Act of 1993 in the U.S., all bank debt is
subordinated to deposits at domestic offices and the FDIC. Thus, for
this proposal, the term “subdebt” is no longer necessary in the U.S.,
except at the bank holding company level. Increasing
criticism has also been voiced by the European Central Bank and the
Institute of International Finance, the major trade association
representing large banks in major countries.
References
Basel Committee on Banking Supervision,
The New Basel Capital Accord (Consultative Document), Basel,
Switzerland: Bank for International Settlements, April 2003a.
Basel Committee on Banking Supervision,
Markets for Bank Subordinated Debt and Equity in Basel Committee Member
Countries (Working Paper No. 12), Basel, Switzerland: Bank for
International Settlements, August 2003b.
Benston, George J., Robert A. Eisenbeis,
Paul M. Horvitz, Edward J. Kane, and George G. Kaufman, Perspectives on
Safe and Sound Banking, Cambridge, MA.: MIT Press, 1986.
Benston, George J. and George G. Kaufman,
“The Intellectual History of the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation
Improvement Act of 1991,” in George Kaufman, ed., Reforming Financial
Institutions and Markets in the United States, Boston: Kluwer Academic,
1994, pp. 1-18.
Bliss, Robert R. and Mark J. Flannery,
“Market Discipline in the Governance of U.S. Bank Holding Companies:
Monitoring vs. Influence,” European Finance Review, Vol. 6, No. 3, 2002,
pp. 361-395.
Borio, Claudio, Craig Furfine, and Philip
Lowe, “Procyclicality of the Financial System and Financial Stability:
Issues and Policy Options,” in Marrying the Macro- and Microprudential
Dimensions of Financial Stability (BIS Papers No. 1), Basel: Bank for
International Settlements, March 2001.
Evanoff, Douglas D. and Larry D. Wall,
“Subordinated Debt and Prompt Corrective Regulatory Action” in George
Kaufman, ed., Prompt Corrective Action in Banking: 10 Years Later,
Amsterdam: Elsevier Science, 2002, pp. 3-29.
Federal Register, “Risk-Based
Capital Guidelines: Proposed Rule and Notice” Washington, D.C.,
August 4, 2003, pp. 45900-45988.
Ferguson, Roger W., “Basel II: Scope of
Application in the United Sates,” Washington, D.C.: Board of Governors
of the Federal Reserve System, June 10, 2003.
Ferguson, Roger W., “Testimony Before the
Subcommittee on Financial Institutions and Consumer Credit Committee on
Financial Services, U.S. House of Representatives,” Washington, D.C.:
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, June 19, 2003.
Hawke, John D., “Testimony Before the
Committee on Financial Services, U.S. House of Representatives,”
Washington, D.C., Comptroller of the Currency, February 27, 2003a.
Hawke, John D., “Remarks Before the
Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs, U.S. Senate”
(NR2003-50), Washington D.C.: Comptroller of the Currency, June 18,
2003b.
Herring, Richard J. and Robert E. Litan,
Financial Regulation in the Global Economy, Washington, D.C.: Brookings
Institution, 1995.
Jagtiani, Julapa, George Kaufman, and
Catharine Lemieux, “The Effect of Credit Risk on Bank and Bank Holding
Company Bond Yields,” Journal of Financial Research, Winter 2002,
pp. 559-575.
Kaufman, George G., “The U.S. Banking
Debacle of the 1980s,” The Financer, May 1995, pp. 9-26.
Kaufman, George G., “Too-Big-To-Fail: Quo
Vadis?” in Benton Gup, ed., Too-Big-To-Fail: Policies and Practices,
Greenwood Publishers, 2003a (forthcoming).
Kaufman, George G., “FDIC Losses in Bank
Failures: Has FDICIA Made a Difference?” Working Paper, Chicago: Loyola
University Chicago, August 2003b.
Laeven, Luc and Giovanni, Majnoni, “Loan
Loss Provisioning and Economic Slowdowns: Too Much, Too Late?” Journal
of Financial Intermediation, April 2003, pp. 178-197.
Lopez, Jose A., “Disclosure as a
Supervisory Tool: Pillar 3 of Basel II,” FRBSF Economic Letter, August
1, 2003.
Shadow Financial Regulatory Committee,
Reforming Bank Capital Regulation, Washington D.C.: American Enterprise
Institute, 2000.
Table 1
SUMMARY OF
PROMPT CORRECTIVE ACTION PROVISIONS OF THE FEDERAL DEPOSIT INSURANCE CORPORATION IMPROVEMENT ACT OF 1991
Zone
|
Mandatory
Provisions
|
Discretionary
Provisions
|
Capital Ratios (percent)
Risk Based Leverage
Total
|
Capital Ratios (percent)
Risk Based Leverage
Tier 1
|
Capital Ratios (percent)
Risk Based Leverage
Tier 1
|
1. Well
Capitalized |
|
|
>10 |
>6 |
>5 |
2.
Adequately
Capitalized |
1. No
brokered deposits except with FDIC approval |
1. Order
recapitalization
2. Restrict inter-affiliate transactions
3. Restrict deposit interest rates
4. Restrict certain other activities
5. Any other action that would better carry out prompt corrective
action |
>8 |
>4 |
>4 |
3.
Undercapitalized |
1. Suspend
dividends and management fees
2. Require capital restoration plan
3. Restrict asset growth
4. Approval required for acquisitions, branching, and new activities
5. No brokered deposits |
1. Any zone
3 discretionary actions
2. Conservatorship or receivership if fails to submit or implement
plan or recapitalize pursuant to order
3. Any other Zone 5 provision, if such action is necessary to carry
out prompt corrective action |
<8 |
<4 |
<4 |
4.
Significantly Undercapitalized |
1. Same as
for Zone 3
2. Order recapitalization*
3. Restrict inter-affiliate transactions*
4. restrict deposit interest rates*
5. Pay of officers restricted |
|
<6 |
<3 |
<3 |
5.
Critically undercapitalized |
1. Same as
for Zone 4
2. Receiver if still in Zone 5 four quarters after becoming
critically under-capitalized
4. Suspend payments to subordinated debt
5. Restrict certain other activities |
|
|
|
<2** |
* Not required if primary supervisor
determines action would not serve purpose of prompt corrective action if
certain conditions are met.
** Tangible equity
Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
|