WELLS FARGO
November 12, 2003
To: Addressees
Re: Advanced Notice of Proposed
Rulemaking
Wells Fargo & Company appreciates the
opportunity to participate in the ongoing dialogue on the Basel capital
reform proposal. We are a diversified financial services company,
providing banking, insurance, investments, mortgage and consumer finance
from more than 5,600 stores, as well as through the Internet and other
distribution channels across North America. As such, we have a keen
interest in the framing of the Basel Accord and hope that the comments
that we offer in this paper will be of assistance in providing solutions
to the issues that exist in the current proposal.
Sincerely,
Howard I. Atkins
Executive Vice President and Chief Financial Officer
Addressees:
Docket No. R
Ms. Jennifer J. Johnson, Secretary
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
20th Street and Constitution Avenue, NW
Washington, DC 20551
Docket No. 03
Communications Division
Third Floor
Office of the Comptroller of the Currency
250 E Street, SW
Washington, DC 20219
Mr. Robert E. Feldman, Executive
Secretary
Attention: Comments
Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation
550 17th Street, NW
Washington, DC 20429
Wells Fargo & Company appreciates the
opportunity to participate in the ongoing dialogue on the Basel capital
reform proposal. While we respect the tremendous amount of time and
effort that has gone in to shaping the proposal, we find that we still
have some fundamental differences of opinion with the path on which the
Basel Committee and the U.S. banking supervisors are proceeding and feel
that certain aspects of the proposal must be changed in order for it to
be acceptable.
We will direct our comments here to the
Advanced Notice of Proposed Rulemaking ("ANPR") published in the Federal
Register on August 3, 2003. We have drafted separate comment letters for
the related Draft Supervisory Guidance on Internal Ratings-Based Systems
for Corporate Credit and the Draft Supervisory Guidance on Operational
Risk Advanced Measurement Approaches for Regulatory Capital, although we
may allude to some of that commentary in the course of this dialogue.
We expect that there will be a relatively
uniform set of concerns that are communicated to the U.S. banking
supervisors with respect to the ANPR - excessive conservatism, undue
prescriptiveness, questionable treatment of expected losses and the loan
loss reserve in the capital calculations, and inadequate recognition of
risk mitigation actions, to name a few. We share and support. these
concerns, and will offer similar comments in the course of this letter.
However, these issues relate primarily to
the risk-based capital calculation itself. In the final analysis, this
calculation is not critical to Wells Fargo, insofar as our pricing
decisions are based not on regulatory capital, but rather on internal
economic capital analyses. Moreover, we are convinced that, if any
risk-weighting concessions are granted by the Basel Committee and the
U.S. banking supervisors in reaction to the comments received on ANPR,
they will shortly thereafter be reclaimed through a new calibration of
the risk-weighting formulas present in Pillar 1, or through different
Pillar 2 requirements. How else will the Basel Committee manage to keep
the overall level of capital in the banking system unchanged,
particularly if the only banks in the U.S. that are subject to the
Accord will be those with a tendency toward diminished capital
requirements under the new system?
Therefore, the primary points that we
will emphasize, and where we feel that we must be successful in helping
the Basel Committee and the U.S. regulatory authorities implement a more
appropriate regulatory capital regime, are in those areas where we
believe that the Accord has ventured beyond its intended scope.
1. First and foremost, we believe that
the Accord has become entirely too prescriptive and inflexible in its
vision of the risk management processes to which banks must adhere.
This is in stark contrast to the original supposition of Basel II --
that each bank would be allowed to continue the use of its existing risk
management practices, so long as they could be shown to have been
effective over time. The Accord should only aspire to establish a
more risk-sensitive framework for constructing minimum bank regulatory
capital requirements. It cannot, and should not, attempt to dictate how
banks actually manage risk. For those institutions, like Wells Fargo,
with proven risk management processes in place, it would be imprudent,
and perhaps dangerous, for them to make significant changes to their
risk management systems in the absence of quantifiable and validated
data that clearly demonstrates that an alternate system is more robust
and accurate, and could be successfully inculcated into their risk
management process.
Do the Basel Committee and the U.S.
banking regulators really intend to force the migration of
well-functioning, customized risk management processes into an untested,
complex framework with the potential to actually confuse, or undermine,
the control and understanding that banks currently have of their credit
portfolios?
2. The decision of the U.S. banking
regulators to require only 10 U.S. banks to comply with the Accord
increases the likelihood of creating an uneven playing field for
major competitors in the U.S. financial services industry. Wells
Fargo is large. However, our credit portfolios, customers, and risk
profile more closely resembles that of smaller regional and community
banks than larger, internationally-active, money center institutions.
The deliberate creation of a bifurcated capital regime sets the stage
for instances where direct competitors will not be subject to the same
capital standards. It is likely that these inequities will be
particularly meaningful to those institutions, like Wells Fargo, that
are widely diversified by line of business and geography and,
consequently, faced with a wider variety of smaller, heterogeneous
competitors.
3. The Pillar 3 disclosure
requirements of the Accord remain overly prescriptive, inappropriate,
and unnecessary. We believe that the Pillar 3 requirements are not
appropriate because public disclosure requirements ought to be set
solely by those agencies that safeguard the interests of investors
(i.e., the SEC, the FASB, and the rating agencies), not by banking
supervisors who have neither the responsibility, the focus, nor the
expertise to take on that role. Furthermore, such requirements seem
unnecessary to us, because, quite outside of Basel, the market will
dictate those elements of bank risk management disclosure that are most
necessary to improve transparency.
We feel compelled to raise these issues,
and others that we will enumerate, not only because they are important
to us, but because we are concerned that the support that may exist for
the Basel proposal within the banking community today stems not from a
philosophical agreement with the direction of the Accord, but either
from the fact that many may view the Accord as a fait accompli
and are "jumping on the bandwagon" or, more narrowly, from the
standpoint of whether or not a particular bank anticipates that it will
receive a lower regulatory capital requirement under the new system.
After all, if one accepts that all banks are, in principle, trying to
maximize return on internal economic capital, subject to the constraint
that economic capital be less than regulatory capital (in total), then
regulatory capital becomes inconsequential to the risk/return
proposition, except for the fact that banks will always argue for
a less binding constraint (that is, lower regulatory capital). With
Basel II, there is a further consideration in this equation, in terms of
the considerable compliance costs that the Accord will impose on the
banking system, an additional sunk cost without compensatory return. We
feel that the Basel Committee and the U.S. banking regulators should
take the time required to resolve many of the issues that the banking
industry is raising at this critical juncture, rather than attempting to
force such a controversial system into premature implementation.
We have organized our comments so as to
respond to the questions on which the ANPR requested specific feedback
and which are most significant for Wells Fargo. Other issues that we
feel are important to raise are included at the end of our letter.
Question #1 pp 23-24
Competitive Considerations
What are commenters' views on the
relative pros and cons of a bifurcated regulatory framework versus a
single regulatory framework? Would a bifurcated approach lead to an
increase in industry consolidation? Why or why not? What are the
competitive implications for community and mid-size regional banks?
Would institutions outside of the core group be compelled for
competitive reasons to opt-in to the advanced approaches? Under what
circumstances might this occur and what are the implications? What are
the competitive implications of continuing to operate under a
regulatory capital
framework that is not risk sensitive?
If regulatory minimum capital
requirements declined under the advanced approaches, would the dollar
amount of capital these banking organizations hold also be expected to
decline? To the extent that advanced approach institutions have lower
capital charges on certain assets, how probable and significant are
concerns that those institutions would realize competitive benefits in
terms of pricing credit, enhanced returns on equity, and potentially
higher risk-based capital ratios? To what extent do similar effects
already exist under the current general risk-based capital rules
(e.g., through securitization or other techniques that lower relative
capital charges on particular assets for only some institutions)? If
they do exist now, what is the evidence of competitive harm?
Apart from the approaches described
in this ANPR, are there other regulatory capital approaches that are
capable of ameliorating competitive concerns while at the same time
achieving the goal of better matching regulatory capital to economic
risks? Are there specific modifications to the proposed approaches or
to the general risk-based capital rules that the Agencies should
consider?
The ANPR proposes that only banks with
total banking assets of $250 billion or more or total on-balance-sheet
foreign exposure of $10 billion or more be required to comply with the
Advanced IRB and AMA approaches of the Accord. We understand that this
will limit the extent of U.S. compliance to roughly 10 U.S. banks,
although others may be allowed to "opt-in." We believe that this
decision increases the likelihood of creating an uneven playing field
for major competitors in the U.S. financial services industry.
Activities that, we feel, receive particularly onerous treatment in the
Accord, such as retail lending and operational risk (e.g., transaction
processing and asset management), would gain an undue advantage when
offered outside of the Accord, either by non-bank competitors or other
large banks.
Although we have not seen a list of the
10 mandatory "Basel Banks" in the U.S., we estimate that many of the
institutions that we compete with most directly in our various regional
markets may not be subjected to Basel's strict compliance standards and
costs. Wells Fargo competes directly against smaller regional and
community banks within the geographic footprint in which our respective
banking franchises operate, yet they would not be subject to the same
capital standards simply because they do not have the same scale of
business as we do outside of this geographic footprint, but within the
U.S.
A number of banks that are as large or
larger than Wells Fargo in terms of particular product lines, but
smaller than our Bank in terms of total assets, would not be subject to
the same capital standards merely because they are not as diversified as
we. Other examples of potential competitive inequality include monoline
non-bank competitors in the credit card and retail lending business, as
well as some of the largest institutions offering personal and
institutional asset management. Across the sphere of diversified
financial services that Wells Fargo offers, there will be meaningful
instances where our direct competitors will not be taxed to the extent
that we will be, simply because they do not enjoy the business diversity
and economies of scale that we do.
With respect to competition, our
contention would be that size is not the same as risk, and that an
arbitrary measure like total assets is not the only, or best, way to
measure either size or risk. The only fair way to enforce the Basel
standards is to apply them to all banks, using the full range of options
(Standard, Foundation, Advanced) that Basel envisions. If the U.S.
regulators deem it necessary to impose the Advanced IRB (A-IRB) approach
to Credit Risk on the largest U.S. banking institutions, in light of
credit risk being the predominant risk that banks undertake as a matter
of course, we believe that in order to lessen the competitive
equality issues, the managed asset size threshold for mandatory A-IRB
compliance should be reduced so as to include the top 50 U.S. banks, and
that smaller banks should be required to adopt either the Standard or
Foundation approach. While such a bifurcated system might result in
higher credit capital requirements for smaller banks, it is the smaller
banks that historically have had the greatest frequency of failure and
the less-developed risk management processes. This approach is the only
way, we feel, to adequately address both competitive equality and safety
and soundness considerations.
In contrast, because there is no accepted
methodology for quantifying Operational Risk, we also believe that the
AMA approach to Operational Risk should not be the sole option that is
made available to U.S. banks. We will expand on this thought in our
commentary below that is specific to Operational Risk.
Question #2 pp 26-27
US Banking Subsidiaries of Foreign Banking Organizations
The Agencies are interested in
comment on the extent to which alternative approaches to regulatory
capital are implemented across national boundaries might create
burdensome implementation costs for the US. subsidiaries of foreign
banks.
We believe that the home country capital
rules should apply to U.S. subsidiaries of foreign banks, and vice
versa, in order to minimize confusion and compliance costs within the
parent holding company.
Question #3 p. 29
Other Considerations - General Banks
The Agencies seek comment on whether
changes should be made to the existing general risk-based capital
rules to enhance the risk-sensitivity or to reflect changes in the
business lines or activities of banking organizations without imposing
undue regulatory burden or complication. In particular, the Agencies
seek comment on whether any changes to the general risk-based capital
rules are necessary or warranted to address any competitive equity
concerns associated with the bifurcated framework.
We believe that the existing risk-based
capital rules should be replaced by Basel II's Standard Approach for
those banks not mandated, or electing, to adopt the Advanced IRB
Approach.
Question #4 p. 30
Majority-Owned or Controlled Subsidiaries
The Federal Reserve specifically
seeks comment on the appropriate regulatory capital treatment for
investments by bank holding companies in insurance underwriting
subsidiaries as well as other nonbank subsidiaries that are subject to
minimum regulatory capital requirements.
We do not understand the rationale for
deconsolidating insurance subsidiaries from the New Accord. To do so
would ignore the diversification benefit that insurance businesses bring
to traditional commercial banking operations. Furthermore, the isolation
of insurance subsidiaries might promote the practice of bank holding
companies arbitraging the different capital standards of their insurance
and banking entities.
Questions # 5 pp 32
Transitional Arrangements
Given the general principle that the
advanced approaches are expected to be implemented at the same time
across all material portfolios, business lines, and geographic
regions, to what degree should the Agencies be concerned that, for
example, data may not be available for key portfolios, business lines,
or regions? Is there a need for further transitional arrangements?
Please be specific, including suggested durations for such
transitions.
Do the projected dates provide an
adequate timeframe for core banks to be ready to implement the
advanced approaches? What other options should the Agencies consider?
The Agencies seek comment on
appropriate thresholds for determining whether a portfolio, business
line, or geographic exposure would be material. Considerations should
include relative asset size, percentages of capital, and associated
levels of risk for a given portfolio, business line, or geographic
region.
We believe that the transitional
arrangements should be modified as follows:
• There should be a push-back in
starting date equal to the amount of time after 12/31/03 that the U.S.
finalizes its rule.
• Each core bank should be able to work
with supervisors to have a staggered start time (after the pushed back
time) for certain business lines for which data problems exist that
cannot be expeditiously solved.
• Each core bank should be permitted to
use a Basel Standardized capital allocation for those business lines
that are in a transition - again, as determined by supervisory review.
• We see no reason for having different
historical data requirements for different business lines or for
different types of risk parameters (e.g., PD versus LGD). Five years
of data for everything would seem an appropriate minimum standard
after the transition period.
• The ANPR appears to omit a data
transitional period as provided for in CP3, implying that the 5 years
of data (or 7 years) are necessary at the beginning of the parallel
calculation period. For some business lines, gathering of data
retroactively is simply not possible. Rather, regulators might require
at least 2 years of data at the beginning of 2006 (the beginning of
the parallel calculation period, assuming no push back), with
additional years of data to be added as time progresses. Full
implementation with at least 5 years of data would then imply a 3-year
transitional period beginning with the start of the parallel
calculation period. This would permit banks to begin compiling data
early in 2004 (or later, if the final U.S. implementation plans are
delayed beyond the end of this year) on those business lines that had
not been adequately documented previously.
Question #6 p. 40
Expected Losses vs. Unexpected Losses
The Agencies seek comment on the
conceptual basis of the A-IRB approach, including all of the aspects
just described. What are the advantages and disadvantages of the A-IRB
approach relative to alternatives, including those that would allow
greater flexibility to use internal models and those that would be
more cautious in incorporating statistical techniques (such as greater
use of credit ratings by external rating agencies)? The Agencies also
encourage comment on the extent to which the model's necessary
conditions of the conceptual justification for the A-IRB approach are
reasonably met, and if nor, what adjustments or alternative approach
would be warranted.
With respect to the conceptual basis for
the A-IRB approach, we believe that Pillar 1 contains excessive
conservatism that would, in aggregate, significantly overstate
banks' need for capital and would propose that either Pillar 1 be
modified to be more consistent with bank risk estimation practices or
that Pillar 2 be expanded to create a forum for banks to present
evidence in support of their contradiction of the Pillar 1 formulae.
Examples of the proposed Accord's conservatism include the following:
1) No capital relief is given for
credit portfolio diversification - At Wells Fargo, we believe that
we have consciously crafted a distinct competitive advantage by virtue
of the diversity of our underlying businesses. Between mortgage banking,
commercial banking, insurance, retail deposit taking, and asset
management services (to name a few of our over 80 businesses), along
with the significant economies of scale that we have in each of these
businesses, we feel that Wells Fargo has created a portfolio of risks
(both credit and non-credit) whose worst-case loss potential is
substantially less than the sum of its parts. In fact, when we have
simply modeled portfolio losses across all of our various credit
portfolios in the past, we typically have concluded that the worst-case
overall credit portfolio result is roughly 65-75% of the raw summation
of the individual sub-portfolio worst-case events - a significant
impact. We also understand that the capture of such capital benefits may
be allowed under the AMA modeling of operational risk. If this is, in
fact, the case, then why would this logic not extend to the modeling of
capital for credit risk, where the impact is more substantive and more
empirically justifiable?
2) 99.9% confidence level as a minimum
standard - The Accord employs a 99.9% confidence level (roughly a
single-A debt rating for a one-year horizon) as the minimum
capital requirement before potential Pillar 2 and "well-capitalized"
increments are taken into account. We would recommend either setting the
minimum standard closer to a level associated with a low investment
grade rating, or employing the 99.9% level as the well-capitalized
standard (after stress tests and FDICIA prompt corrective action
provisions have been take into account).
3) Unrealistic asset correlation
assumptions - The Accord employs unrealistically high asset
correlation assumptions in the risk-weighted asset calculations, which
make the estimated 99.9th percentile loss level arbitrarily high in the
first place. These assumptions result in an exaggerated view of
worst-case loss levels across all of the retail lending product
categories, and are particularly misrepresentative in the case of
high-EL/high-FMI (non-prime) retail lending.
4) Stress testing requirements -
The Accord requires stress tests to the 99.9th percentile calculations,
which may translate into required capital in excess of the 99.9th
percentile. We do not understand the need for such a required
incremental capital buffer, if so high a minimum confidence level has
already been assessed.
5) Omission of the tax consequences of
losses - The Accord fails to recognize the fact that worst-case
losses should be supported by capital on an after-tax, rather than
pre-tax, basis, thereby reducing the amount of capital required. After
all, the actual drain on retained earnings occasioned by most losses is
inclusive of the tax benefit associated with those losses. The omission
of this benefit effectively overstates the required capital support for
a business by 30-40%!
6) Treatment of Goodwill as Capital
- Subsequent to the inception of the existing Risk-Based Capital Accord
in 1988, the accounting principles (GAAP) that affect the treatment of
the Goodwill asset on the balance sheet have changed. Under GAAP today,
Goodwill must be revalued to its fair market value on a quarterly basis.
As such, we believe that Goodwill now represents an asset with an
accepted value equal to its recorded balance sheet amount, and should no
longer be a required deduction from Tier 1 Capital in the regulatory
capital calculations. In contrast to other banking assets that, by GAAP
standards, are subjected to similar impairment analyses on an ongoing
basis, the capital treatment of Goodwill is disproportionately harsh.
7) Additional capital for
"well-capitalized" standard - As we understand it, in the U.S. the
well-capitalized standard under the FDICIA prompt corrective action
provisions may impose an additional 2.00% total capital requirement on
banks, on top of the conservatism already built into the assumptions
above.
Question #6 p. 40 (continued)
Expected Losses vs. Unexpected Losses
Should the A-IRB capital regime be
based on a framework that allocates capital to EL plus UL, or to UL
only? Which approach would more closely align the regulatory framework
to the internal capital allocation techniques currently used by large
institutions? If the framework were recalibrated solely to UL,
modifications to the rest of the A-IRB framework would be required.
The Agencies seek commenters' views on issues that would arise as a
result of such recalibration.
As a separate issue from the use of the
ALLL in the capital calculation, Wells Fargo supports the widely held
industry belief that capital is not needed to cover EL because bank
pricing practices are generally constructed such that pricing covers
expected losses, other expenses, and a targeted minimum return on
economic capital. Stated differently, risk does not emanate from losses
that are expected and priced for; it is created by uncertainty, in terms
of unexpected credit events or mis-managed operating leverage.
Consequently, we would suggest that EL be
excluded from the computation of required capital. If this treatment is
not adopted, it seems to us that the only fair approach is to permit
consideration of those elements that act as offsets to EL in practice -
the full amount of the loan loss reserve and an appropriate portion of
Future Margin Income. We believe that excluding EL from the capital
calculation would be the simpler and, actually, more conservative, in
terms of resulting in a higher capital requirement when compared to the
alternative of subtracting Future Margin Income.
We would also point out that, in its
current form, the Accord is internally inconsistent in its treatment of
EL. It permits Future Margin Income to offset EL in the case of
qualifying revolving retail exposures and operational risk, but does not
allow it for any other banking risks. We find this illogical, and would
suggest that a consistent treatment of FMI (as an offset to EL) be used
across all banking products.
Question # 7 p. 46
Wholesale Exposures: Definitions and Inputs
The Agencies seek comment on the
proposed definition of wholesale exposures and on the proposed inputs
to the wholesale A-IRB capital formulas. What are views on the
proposed definitions of default, PD, LGD, EAD, and M2 Are there
specific issues with the standards for the quantification of PD, LGD,
EAD, or M on which the Agencies should focus?
Of the proposed inputs to the wholesale
A-IRB capital formulas, the only one that Wells Fargo has a significant
issue with is the definition of default, itself. We believe that
the definition of default outlined in CP3 and the ANPR should be
simplified to correspond more closely to what is more commonly used by
risk practitioners. That is, loans that fall under the corporate and
specialized lending models should define default to coincide solely with
the incidence of nonaccrual or charge-off status (to exclude the 90 days
past due and other isolated conditions present in the Accord's current
definition), and loans that fall under the retail model should define
default to coincide with the Uniform Retail Credit Classification
standards published by the FFIEC.
With respect to retail lending, the ANPR
presents an updated point of view from the U.S. banking supervisors that
the FFIEC definitions of loss recognition for retail credit will
prevail. However, the ANPR goes on to state that retail default will
also include the occurrence of any of the following events: 1) full or
partial charge-off, 2) a distressed restructuring or workout involving
forbearance and loan modification; or 3) notification that the obligor
has sought or been placed in bankruptcy. We believe that the retail
charge-off and bankruptcy conditions are addressed in the FFIEC
guidelines, and, as such, would be appropriately triggered as defaults
by those procedures. However, the distressed restructuring criterion is
outside of the scope of FFIEC and should be excluded from the Basel
definition of default.
Our comments here will address primarily
the application of the default definition to corporate and specialized
lending portfolios. We are concerned that, in the absence of moving the
Basel default definition for wholesale loans to be based solely on the
occurrence of non-accrual or charge-off status, banks will be forced
to track two separate measures of default - one for internal risk
assessment and a second for regulatory capital purposes. This would
seem to be a meaningless, yet costly, exercise, since the ultimate
driver of risk is loss, and these fine lines of default definition
will only serve to shift the mix of PD and LGD in an offsetting fashion,
without significantly affecting ultimate loss.
Non-Accrual status already subsumes the
more detailed definitions of default. Generally, an asset is placed on
non-accrual when it is 90 days past due or when reasonable doubt exists
about a loan's collectibility. And, a declaration of bankruptcy would
almost certainly trigger the condition of reasonable doubt regarding
collectibility.
An exception to these general rules
occurs when a loan is well secured and in the process of collection, in
which case it will not necessarily be placed on non-accrual status.
However, this exception only applies in limited situations. To be well
secured, the asset must be secured by lien or pledge of collateral with
realizable value sufficient to fully meet the obligation or guaranteed
by a financially responsible party. An asset is in the process of
collection if the collection through legal or other means is in due
course. Generally, an asset can only remain that status for 30 days
unless it can be demonstrated that the amount and timing of the payment
is sufficient and reasonably certain.
There are already internal controls,
internal audits, external audits and supervisory processes to ensure
that non-accrual and charge-off policies are applied correctly. These
policies, which govern whether banks continue to recognize income on
their financial statements, should be sufficient to satisfy the Basel
definition of default. The broader IRB definition of default, which
includes bankruptcy, selling at a loss, distressed restructuring (either
wholesale or retail), and 90 days past due, is likely to arrive at
virtually the same overall conclusion regarding the frequency of
defaults, once consideration is given to materiality and purely
technical defaults are excluded.
The U.S. banking supervisors seem overly
concerned regarding the potential for "silent defaults;" that is,
instances where the well secured and in the process of collection
exceptions to non-accrual policies are triggered. Capturing this data is
a meaningless exercise for two reasons. First, these are exceptions
precisely because there is a strong expectation of zero loss. And,
second, as we previously stated, the net result of tagging such events
as defaults would be negligible, since increased PD estimates would be
offset by lower LGD estimates.
The same thought process around silent
defaults also seems to have driven the additional criterion to include
loan sales at material credit related discounts as defaulted assets. We
oppose this criterion on both practical and conceptual grounds. Loan
sales are a part of the portfolio management function. Portfolio
management strategies differ significantly across banks, with some
institutions being much more active than others. Even within a single
institution, loan sale strategies will vary across time depending on
overall balance sheet management and liquidity issues. Clearly,
including performing loan sales in the definition of default would
introduce comparability problems. Further, discounts on loan sales
can be due to a variety of factors unrelated to credit such as interest
rates, liquidity or technical supply and demand issues. It would be
quite difficult, and ultimately arbitrary, to disentangle these effects.
Finally, on a more fundamental level, the
loss in a loan's value due to credit deterioration is migration risk and
not default risk. Migration risk is already included in the framework
through the maturity adjustment portion of the IRB formula. To be
consistent with the derivation of the formula, the default probability
that is estimated should not be artificially inflated for downgrades,
and then only for those that are "realized" through discretionary loan
sales. Such regulation could create perverse incentives for bank credit
portfolio management and actually add to risk in the portfolio.
One final issue that we would like to
point out with the definition of default is its interplay with paragraph
366 of CP3. Paragraph 366 prescribes that banks must have one point on
their borrower rating scales that is reserved solely for defaulted
loans. We see no reason why it should be necessary to create a risk
rating bucket that, by design, has a 100% PD, so long as a bank would
always be able to identify what the actual default rate is for each of
its rating buckets. While it is highly likely that defaulting borrowers
would congregate at the lower end of a rating scale, we do not think
that a unilateral default rating construct should be prescribed to
banks. However, the mandate for a single default bucket becomes a
potentially bigger issue when added to the fact that we disagree with
the proposed definition of default in the first place. Without some
change in the default definition, banks would be faced with the
unnecessary cost of actually creating parallel risk rating methodologies
- one for internal risk assessment and a second for regulatory capital
purposes, with no value added to the risk management process, and,
indeed, the potential to create confusion among those responsible for
identifying and managing risk in the portfolio.
Of secondary, but still meaningful,
importance to Wells Fargo is the language in the ANPR which suggests
that conservatism be built into the estimates provided for EAD and LGD
by limiting, for example, the underlying observation set to recessionary
periods. We believe that EAD and LGD should be estimated using a
"default-weighted" process that is naturally weighted toward periods
with high defaults. Stressed parameters, such as recessionary EAD's and
recessionary LGD's, should be used separately in stress analyses.
Question # 8 p. 52
Wholesale Exposures: SME Adjustment
If the Agencies include a SME
adjustment, are the $50 million threshold and the proposed approach to
measurement of borrower size appropriate? What standards should be
applied to the borrower size measurement (for example, frequency of
measurement, use of size buckets rather than precise measurements) ?
Does the proposed borrower size
adjustment add a meaningful element of risk sensitivity sufficient to
balance the costs associated with its computation? The Agencies are
interested in comments on whether it is necessary to include an SME
adjustment in the A-IRB approach. Data supporting views is encouraged.
The capital formulation for SME's (small
and medium-sized enterprises) should be simplified so that it is not so
complex and, potentially, costly for banks to comply with, in terms of
assembling the required data. There is little theoretical support for
modeling borrower asset correlation as so granular a function of sales
size as is suggested by the Accord. We do not understand why a single,
lower asset correlation specification could not be devised, using the
same functional form, but lower parameter settings, as the Corporate
risk weight function, while simply stipulating a maximum sales size for
a borrower to be considered an SME (we believe that $50 million
threshold suggested is reasonable). Ideally, this function could also be
made to eliminate the arbitrage possibilities that currently exist
between corporate and retail SME risk weightings.
Question # 9 p. 54
Wholesale Exposures: Specialized Lendinq
The Agencies invite comment on ways
to deal with cyclicality in LGDs. How can risk sensitivity be achieved
without creating undue burden?
We do not believe that cyclicality in
minimum regulatory capital requirements is a problem, so long as minimum
regulatory capital is somewhat below the economic capital levels that
banks' internal risk models would suggest. In this way, banks would
naturally be led to hold a cushion for volatility in their
capital-setting policies. Therefore, using long-run average LGD
estimates that incorporate periods of recession is preferable to using
recession-only LGD estimates (which would introduce a bias for
regulatory capital to be too high throughout the rest of the cycle).
This point applies to all forms of lending, not just Specialized
Lending.
With respect to Specialized Lending (and,
specifically, investor/developer real estate lending), it should be
noted that the cyclicality mentioned in the ANPR with respect to LGD
will spill over into the PD estimates for such a portfolio, given the
correlation between PD and LGD. As a result, certain scenarios can occur
in which different obligations for a given borrower may have different
PD's. This outcome is counter to one of the Supervisory Guidance's
prescribed principles for obligor rating scales. We offer a possible
solution to this issue in our response to the following question.
Question #10 p. 55
Wholesale Exposures: Specialized Lendinq
The Agencies invite comment on the
merits of the SSC approach in the United States. The Agencies also
invite comment on the specific slotting criteria and associated risk
weights that should be used by organizations to map their internal
risk rating grades to supervisory rating grades if the SSC approach
were to be adopted in the United States.
Paragraph 362 of CP3 describes an
exemption from the two-dimensional rating system design requirement that
is available to banks using the supervisory slotting criteria. It states
that "given the interdependence between borrower/transaction
characteristics in Specialized Lending, banks may satisfy the
requirements under this heading through a single rating dimension that
reflects EL by incorporating both borrower strength (PD) and loss
severity (LGD) considerations." We agree about the presence of
significant correlation between PD and LGD in commercial real estate
lending, and feel that Advanced IRB banks should be allowed the same
flexibility to use a single rating scale to assess risk in
investor/developer real estate lending. We believe that this would be a
much more reliable manner in which to capture the collateral-intensive
nature of that business and its correlation with borrower PD.
Question #11 p. 57
Wholesale Exposures: HVCRE
The Agencies invite the submission
of empirical evidence regarding the (relative or absolute) asset
correlations characterizing portfolios of land ADC loans, as well as
comments regarding the circumstances under which such loans would
appropriately be categorized as HVCRE.
The Agencies also invite comment on
the appropriateness of exempting from the high asset correlation
category ADC loans with substantial equity or that are presold or
sufficiently pre-leased. The Agencies invite comment on what standard
should be used in determining whether a property is sufficiently
pre-leased when prevailing occupancy rates are unusually low.
The Agencies invite comment on
whether high asset correlation treatment for one-to four family
residential construction loans is appropriate, or whether they should
be included in the low asset correlation category. In cases where
loans finance the construction of a subdivision or other group of
houses, some of which are pre-sold while others are not, the Agencies
invite comment regarding how the pre-sold" exception should be
interpreted.
The Agencies invite comment on the
competitive impact of treating defined classes of CRE differently.
What are commenters' views on an alternative approach where there is
only one risk weight function for all CRE? If a single asset
correlation treatment were considered, what would be the appropriate
asset correlations to employ within a single risk-weight function
applied to all CRE exposures?
We agree that certain forms of commercial
real estate lending have historically exhibited higher volatility than
traditional forms of corporate lending. It is also true, we believe,
that over the years those commercial real estate lenders that have
experienced several real estate cycles have developed underwriting
strategies to dampen the potential impact on their portfolios of
recessionary real estate environments.
Our perspective is that there is no
"right" answer to what is "high volatility" commercial real estate
lending. Such a definition would certainly be multi-dimensional, rather
than subscribing to a simple, product-based focus. And, a
multi-dimensional alternative would assuredly present compliance and
data maintenance burdens to reporting banks. We would support the
alternative of selecting a simple, directionally correct, definition of
"high volatility" commercial real estate, such as any loans that meet
the Call Reporting definition of Real Estate Construction Lending.
Question # 12 p. 58
Wholesale Exposures: Lease Financinqs
The Agencies are seeking comment on
the wholesale A IRB capital formulas and the resulting capital
requirements. Would this approach provide a meaningful and appropriate
increase in risk sensitivity in the sense that the results are
consistent with alternative assessments of the credit risks associated
with such exposures or the capital needed to support them? If not,
where are there material inconsistencies?
Does the proposed A-IRB maturity
adjustment appropriately address the risk differences between loans
with differing maturities?
We agree that the proposed formulae
result in a reasonable representation of the relative risk of positions
with varying PD's and LGD's. There are two issues that we have with the
formulation. First, we believe that the asset value correlation function
for corporate SME borrowers has been set too high, is overly complex,
and encourages a capital arbitrage between retail SME and corporate SME
(as we discussed above).
Secondly, we believe that the formulaic
capital treatment of very short-term maturities under one year is
excessive. If an obligor has a given probability of default over, say,
the next quarter, the cumulative probability of default over 4 quarters,
even assuming no credit quality deterioration, must be higher than the
one-quarter probability of default. Therefore, unexpected losses must be
less for the short-dated facility. Implicit in this conclusion is the
requirement that the bank have the unquestioned right to cancel the
facility at the end of the current term.
Question # 13 p. 60
Retail Exposures: Definitions and Inputs
The Agencies are interested in
comment on whether the proposed $1 million threshold provides the
appropriate dividing line between those SME exposures that banking
organizations should be allowed to treat on a pooled basis under the
retail A-IRB framework and those SME exposures that should be rated
individually and treated under the wholesale A-IRB framework.
We believe that the line of demarcation
between SME exposures treated as retail and those treated as wholesale
could reasonably be certified under Pillar 2, rather than codified under
Pillar 1. Each bank would be required to show how it manages certain SME
exposures as relatively homogeneous "retail" assets. A threshold such as
$1 million may become quickly outmoded, either due to inflation or due
to the way in which risk management and measurement is carried out at
individual banks.
More importantly, we believe that this
question should really be moot. A better alternative, we believe, would
be to establish a single risk-weighting function for SME that eliminates
the arbitrage possibilities that currently exist between the corporate
and retail SME sub-portfolios.
Question # 14 p. 65
Retail Exposures: Undrawn Lines
The Agencies are interested in
comments and specific proposals concerning methods for incorporating
undrawn credit card lines that are consistent with the risk
characteristics and loss and default histories of this line of
business.
The Agencies are interested in
further information on market practices in this regard, in particular
the extent to which banking organizations remain exposed to risks
associated with such accounts. More broadly, the Agencies recognize
that undrawn credit card lines are significant in both of the contexts
discussed above, and are particularly interested in views on the
appropriate retail IRB treatment of such exposures.
We do not see anything wrong with the
concept of holding capital against undrawn lines of credit. Most retail
risk management practitioners would acknowledge that there is risk is
such commitments that may materialize in the event of default. However,
practitioners would also maintain that there is an interplay between PD
and EAD and, for some products, LGD, such that the sensitivity of the
"bottom-line" losses (EL) cannot be modeled as an uncorrelated response
to one of the latent variables.
Under certain modeling assumptions, this
would not be an insurmountable problem. However, the Basel risk-weight
function uses an assumption of declining asset correlation in relation
to PD, which produces the unintuitive outcome that the EAD assumption
for low PD accounts has an outsized impact on the 99.91h percentile
losses for such accounts. It is these low PD accounts that would have
the lowest usage in the first place. The result is that those accounts
that are most sensitive to EAD also receive the highest asset
correlation in the A-IRB formulation, with the result that their 99.9kh
percentile losses are exaggerated. In order to make the modeled
probability density function of losses for credit cards and unsecured
revolving lines of credit more realistic, we believe that the declining
asset correlation function in the A-IRB capital formulation must be
replaced by a constant asset correlation function.
Question #15 pp. 66-67
Retail Exposures: Future Margin Income
For the QRE sub-category of retail
exposures only, the Agencies are seeking comment on whether or not to
allow banking organizations to offset a portion of the A-IRB capital
requirement relating to expected losses by demonstrating that their
anticipated FMI for this sub-category is likely to more than
sufficiently cover expected losses over the next year.
The Agencies are seeking comment on
the proposed definitions of the retail A-IRB exposure category and
sub-categories. Do the proposed categories provide a reasonable
balance between the need for differential treatment to achieve
risksensitivity and the desire to avoid excessive complexity in the
retail A-IRB framework? What are views on the proposed approach to
inclusion of small-business exposures in the other retail category?
The Agencies are also seeking views
on the proposed approach to defining the risk inputs for the retail A-IRB
framework. Is the proposed degree of flexibility in their calculation,
including the application of specific floors, appropriate? What are
views on the issues associated with undrawn retail lines of credit
described here and on the proposed incorporation of FMI in the QRE
capital determination process?
The Agencies are seeking comment on the minimum time requirements for
data history
and experience with segmentation and risk management systems: Are
these time requirements appropriate during the transition period?
Describe any reasons for not being
able to meet the time requirements.
a) On the topic of EL, see our response
to question #6.
b) We believe that the retail capital
formulation could be made to coincide more closely with industry best
practices by doing away with the three retail formulations that have
been proposed and allowing the asset correlation parameter in the basic
Merton formula to be a variable, rather than hardcoded to have three
distinct values. Banks could then employ asset correlation assumptions
that were customized to the traits of each heterogeneous retail
portfolio.
c) As it stands, the Accord employs
unrealistically high asset correlation assumptions in the risk-weighted
asset calculations, which make the estimated 99.9th percentile loss
level arbitrarily high. These assumptions result in an exaggerated view
of worst-case loss levels across all of the retail lending product
categories, and are particularly misrepresentative in the case of high-EUhigh-FMI
(non-prime) retail lending.
d) As indicated above, the definition of
default used within retail categories should align with reporting
practices of banks. Thus, the FFIEC standard should be used without
embellishment.
e) The proposed approach to estimating
the inputs to the regulatory retail capital models is generally
appropriate. However, no floors should be placed on any estimated
parameter input. The proposed 10% floor on LGDs for single family
mortgages is simply another example of arbitrary and cumulatively
conservative rules. Rather, the appropriateness of PD, LGD, and EAD
estimates is strictly a Pillar 2 issue. That is, the banking supervisors
retain the ability under Pillar 2 to require any AIRB bank to use a
higher PD or LGD input into the regulatory capital models than the bank
would use in the absence of supervision.
f) We also wish to point out that actual implementation by banks of some
of the data gathering aspects of risk measurement for retail products
cannot begin in earnest until the regulators release their supervisory
guidance document regarding retail credits. The requirement for 3 years
worth of experience with the segmentation and risk management systems
are too stringent, especially since the agencies have not yet published
supervisory guidance for retail credit risk. We recommend that this
requirement be softened.
g) On the topic of portfolio segmentation
of retail exposures, page 61 of the ANPR states that one of the
"specific limitations" that the Agencies would propose is that banking
organizations would need to separately segment "delinquent retail
exposures". While Wells Fargo's primary position on the topic is that no
specific requirements should be imposed on retail portfolio
segmentation, we still view the ANPR's statement as being somewhat
vague. We would recommend that the language be modified to make it clear
that, in this context, delinquency can be recognized either through
explicit segmentation (that is, past due versus not past due, or some
variation on the theme) or through the incorporation of delinquent
characteristic(s) in the credit scoring models which a bank might use to
form the basis for its retail product PD estimation.
Question # 16 p.70
Retail Exposures: Private Mortgage Insurance
The Agencies also seek comment on
the competitive implications of allowing PMI recognition for banking
organizations using the A-IRB approach but not allowing such
recognition for general banks. In addition, the Agencies are
interested in data on the relationship between PMI and LGD to help
assess whether it may be appropriate to exclude residential mortgages
covered by PMI from the proposed 10 percent LGD foor. The Agencies
request comment on whether or the extent to which it might be
appropriate to recognize PMI in LGD estimates.
More broadly, the Agencies are
interested in information regarding the risks of each major type of
residential mortgage exposure, including prime first mortgages, sub
prime mortgages, home equity term loans, and home equity lines of
credit. The Agencies are aware of various views on the resulting
capital requirements for several of these product areas, and wish to
ensure that all appropriate evidence and views are considered in
evaluating the A-IRB treatment of these important exposures.
The risk-based capital requirements
for credit risk of prime mortgages could well be less than one percent
of their face value under this proposal. The Agencies are interested
in evidence on the capital required by private market participants to
hold mortgages outside of the federally insured institution and GSE
environment. The Agencies also are interested in views on whether the
reductions in mortgage capital requirements contemplated here would
unduly extend the federal safety net and risk contributing to a
credit-induced bubble in housing prices. In addition, the Agencies are
also interested in views on whether there has been any shortage of
mortgage credit under general risk-based capital rules that would be
alleviated by the proposed changes.
With respect to the question on PMI, we
are puzzled as to why the Basel Committee has even envisioned an LGD
floor for mortgages. It seems out of context with the approach that is
suggested for LGD estimation elsewhere in the Accord. We commented above
on our point of view on cyclicality in LGD's. Residential mortgage loans
with PMI should be no different than any other loan class. Banks should
be required to provide realistic, long-run average estimates of their
LGD's that are default-weighted averages of their experience across an
economic cycle, and not subject to any artificial floors. Under the
Accord's current wording, we would acknowledge that the proposed LGD
floor could have public policy implications, with respect to its impact
on banks who actively use PMI insurance as a tool to facilitate the
granting of loans at attractive rates to borrowers who have not
accumulated a 20% down payment.
On the broader topic of the capital
requirements that result from the proposed A-IRB capital formulation for
mortgage products, we believe that the regulatory asset value
correlation assumptions should be adjusted downward for both first and
second mortgage products. While we acknowledge that the current proposal
provides capital for prime mortgages at a rate significantly below the
old Accord, it should also be noted that the A-IRB formulation addresses
credit capital only. Our internal models would suggest a reasonable
amount of operational risk to the mortgage production and mortgage
servicing businesses, which needs to be aggregated with the credit
capital associated with the mortgages held in portfolio in order to
provide a valid basis for assessing overall capital required by a
mortgage banking business.
Question #17 p. 72-73
Retail Exposures: Future Margin Income Adjustment
The Agencies are interested in views
on whether partial recognition of FMI should be permitted in cases
where the amount of eligible FMI fails to meet the required minimum.
The Agencies are also interested in views on the level of portfolio
segmentation at which it would be appropriate to perform the FMI
calculation. Would a requirement that FMI eligibility calculations be
performed separately for each portfolio segment effectively allow FMI
to offset EL capital requirements for QRE exposures?
We believe that internal capital
generation acts as a primary buffer against losses in the portfolio,
even before loan loss reserves and equity capital are drawn upon. While
this concept has long been valued by bank debt rating agencies in their
evaluation of bank capital structures and securitizations of pools of
assets, it has been virtually ignored in the Accord. Even recent
amendments to the Accord with respect to Future Margin Income are
fundamentally understated, by virtue of restricting their focus to
higher-margin retail lending portfolios and operational risk. Margin
income is found throughout a diversified bank holding company and,
regardless of its source, serves as a component of internal capital
generation. Stated simply, it is not the risk alone of extending credit
that creates a requirement for capital outlay at a financial
institution. It is this risk absent a compensatory reward that raises
capital requirements. We would argue that some fraction of Future Margin
Income should be deducted from all Pillar 1 capital formulations -
wholesale lending, retail lending, and operational risk. FMI excesses in
certain areas should be allowed to subsidize FMI shortfalls in other
areas, since it is the holding company's solvency that is being
evaluated.
Question #18 p. 75-76
Retail Exposures Formula: Other Retail
The Agencies are seeking comment on
the retail A-IRB capital formulas and the resulting capital
requirements, including the specific issues mentioned. Are there
particular retail product lines or retail activities for which the
resulting A-IRB capital requirements would not be appropriate, either
because of a misalignment with underlying risks or because of other
potential consequences?
As mentioned earlier, we believe that the
Accord employs unrealistically high asset correlation assumptions in the
risk-weighted asset calculations, which make the estimated 99.9th
percentile loss level arbitrarily high. These assumptions result in an
exaggerated view of worst-case loss levels across all of the retail
lending product categories, and are particularly misrepresentative in
the case of high-EL/high-FMI (non-prime) retail lending.
Question # 19 p. 77
A-IRB: Other Considerations: Loan Loss Reserves
The Agencies recognize the existence
of various issues in regard to the proposed treatment of ALLL amounts
in excess of the 1.25 percent limit and are interested in views on
these subjects, as well as related issues concerning the incorporation
of expected losses in the A-IRB framework and the treatment of the
ALLL generally. Specifically, the Agencies invite comment on the
domestic competitive impact of the potential difference in the
treatment of reserve 's described.
The Agencies seek views on this
issue, including whether the proposed US. treatment has significant
competitive implications. Feedback also is sought on whether there is
an inconsistency in the treatment of general specific provisions (all
of which may be used as an offset against the EL portion of the A-IRB
capital requirement) in comparison to the treatment of the ALLL (for
which only those amounts ofgeneral reserves exceeding the 1.25 percent
limit may be used to offset the EL capital charge).
We believe that banks should be allowed
to effectively count their entire loan loss reserve (ALLL) as capital,
rather than having its usage capped (at 1.25% of risk-weighted assets (RWA),
or aggregate expected losses (EL)). If usage of the ALLL is capped, a
major portion of three primary buffers against loss volatility -
portfolio diversification, margin income, and part of the loan loss
reserve - will effectively have been ignored. It would also be the case
in this instance that banks with low expected losses would receive an
arbitrary capital advantage, since it is more likely that their ALLL
would "fit" under the 1.25% of RWA cap.
Wells Fargo thinks of the loan loss
reserve as another form of capital. We see no reason why banks should
not be aoie to effectively count their entire ALLL as capital,
regardless of the proposed treatment of EL in the risk-weighted asset
formulae. It is particularly objectionable to us that the current
proposal gives an arbitrary advantage to some banks in terms of their
ability to make full use of their ALLL.
Question #20 p. 82
A-IRB Other: Treatment of undrawn receivables purchase commitments
The Agencies seek comment on the
proposed methods for calculating credit risk capital charges for
purchased exposures. Are the proposals reasonable and practicable?
For committed revolving purchase
facilities, is the assumption of a fixed 75 percent conversion factor
for undrawn advances reasonable? Do banks have the ability (including
relevant data) to develop their own estimate of EADs for such
facilities? Should banks be permitted to employ their own estimated
EADs, subject to supervisory approval?
The agencies should clarify whether the
purchased receivables approach applies to all credit exposures purchased
from third parties or a more limited set of transactions of trade
receivables. We support the flexibility to apply top down methods for
purchased exposures.
The approach in CP3 applies dollar for
dollar capital reduction for the purchase discount. The U.S. agencies
are not comfortable with this approach because it would result in a zero
capital charge for assets where the discount is equal to or greater than
the estimated LGD. In the ANPR, the AIRB formula is applied to the cost
basis of the exposures using either bottom-up or top down estimates of
the parameters. As a result, the dollar capital charge is reduced only
by the amount of the discount times the capital ratio. We believe this
approach is too conservative and not sufficiently risk sensitive. A
better approach would be to scale the LGD in relation to the discount.
We recommend a floor of 25% on the scaling factor be set to assure
non-zero capital assignments.
If the top-down approach applies to
portfolio acquisitions, mergers, whole loan purchases, and secondary
market transactions, the qualifying criteria for this approach are too
stringent. In particular, the requirement that the receivables be
limited to maturities less than one year, unless fully collateralized,
would exclude most retail assets.
With regard to estimated EADs, we see no
reason to have a separate treatment of committed revolving purchase
facilities (i.e., an arbitrary 75% "conversion" factor for undrawn
lines). The Pillar 2 supervision process should govern acceptable EAD
estimates made by individual AIRB banks, as is the case for the other
risk parameters (PD and LGD). Only if supervisors find the internal
process unacceptable should the internal EAD estimate be replaced with a
supervisory requirement for EAD.
Question # 21&22 p. 84
A-IRB Other: Capital Charge for Dilution Risk - Minimum Requirements
The Agencies seek comment on the
proposed methods for calculating dilution risk capital requirements.
Does this methodology produce capital charges for dilution risk that
seem reasonable in light of available historical evidence? Is the
corporate A-IRB capital formula appropriate for computing capital
charges for dilution risk?
In particular, is it reasonable to
attribute the same asset correlations to dilution risk as are used in
quantifying the credit risks of corporate exposures within the A IRB
framework? Are there alternative methods) for determining capital
charges for dilution risk that would be superior to that set forth
above?
The Agencies seek comment on the
appropriate eligibility requirements for using the top-down method.
Are the proposed eligibility requirements, including the $1 million
limit for any single obligor, reasonable and sufficient?
The Agencies seek comment on the
appropriate requirements for estimating expected dilution losses. Is
the guidance set forth in the New Accord reasonable and sufficient?
No specific comment.
Question # 23 p. 91
Credit Risk Mitigation Techniques
The Agencies seek comments on the
methods set forth above for determining EAD, as well as on the
proposed backtesting regime and possible alternatives banking
organizations might find more consistent with their internal risk
management processes for these transactions. The Agencies also request
comment on whether banking organizations should be permitted to use
the standard supervisory haircuts or own estimates haircuts
methodologies that are proposed in the New Accord.
We concur with the broadened recognition
of collateral in the new Accord. This revised treatment of collateral
will better align industry and regulatory practice for this critical
credit risk mitigation tool.
We support the use of collateral haircuts
that are determined internally. Large, highly rated banks tend to be net
collateral receivers, and as such, their incentives to use fiscally
sound haircuts are aligned with those of the U.S. banking supervisors.
Conversely, it would be difficult for large banks to change collateral
arrangements that are already in place, especially since the majority of
counterparties will not be Basel II compliant entities.
In addition, we would like to point out
that certain requirements in CP3 are not in line with large, complex
banks' internal collateral policies.
• Paragraph 125 of CP3 implies that
non-investment grade or unrated corporate bonds would not be eligible
collateral, even for banks that qualify to use their own haircuts. At
the same time, Paragraph 129 of CP3 requires banks using their own
haircuts to take into account the liquidity of lower quality assets -
an issue that is a key consideration in the assignment of our internal
haircuts. Thus, the exclusion of non-investment grade corporate debt
altogether (as opposed to the use of a larger haircut) is unduly harsh
in light of standard haircut practice.
• CP3 requires a separate assessment
for foreign exchange risk even for banks under the AIRB that will be
setting their own haircuts. The separate assessment of foreign
exchange risk presents problems from an implementation standpoint
given that most large, complex banks apply a portfolio view to
collateral. It appears that the CP3 proposal essentially requires
banks to look at each transaction separately to determine whether
there is a currency mismatch. For large portfolios with large
counterparties involving multiple positions, this approach may involve
thousands of transactions -which would make such an approach both
impractical and not best-practice from a portfolio management
standpoint. Typical practice is to agree with a large counterparty on
a schedule of eligible collateral assets and applicable haircuts.
Eligible collateral can include US dollar cash and securities and
certain non-US dollar cash and securities. Most non-US dollar
collateral positions are in euros, yen, and pounds, where there is
generally low volatility over the short period of the exposure. The
counterparty can cover its collateral requirements for its net
exposure by delivering any of the eligible assets. For a portfolio of
such low-volatility currency, short duration positions, currency risk
is negligible and is often not measured for this reason (and if it
were to be measured it would be done on a portfolio basis).
• CP3 requires banks to use a 99%
confidence level in setting their own collateral haircuts. Many banks
may not use such a high confidence level in setting internal haircuts.
To do so would imply an exceedingly low joint probability that the
obligor will default and the collateral value will decline to
insufficient levels. Given the cumulatively conservative prescriptions
elsewhere in the new Accord, including the overall confidence interval
for capital purposes, we believe that the confidence interval for
internal haircuts should be a Pillar 2 (supervisory guidance) issue.
• We believe that there should be
significant conformity in the capital calculations for products that
exhibit similar economic risks, notably repo transactions and OTC
derivatives. Paragraph 149 of CP3 appears to restrict use of the VaR
approach to repostyle transactions. It is not clear from a theoretical
or empirical perspective why supervisors would impose such a
restriction. We also see no reason why repos would be allowed to
adjust EAD in order to reduce exposure for collateral, while
derivatives are required to adjust LGD.
• In addition, any modifications to the
current approach should properly recognize the riskreducing effects of
collateral support agreements, which require the delivery of
collateral upon the breach of pre-agreed thresholds, thereby reducing
potential future exposure.
• Finally, supervisors should permit
VaR modelling for all transactions, not just repo transactions, that
are marked to market and remargined daily, and meet high standards of
legal enforceability (i.e. transactions that comply with paragraphs 88
and 89 of CP3).
Question #24 p. 93
Guarantees and credit derivatives
Industry comment is sought on whether a
more uniform method of adjusting PD or LGD estimates should be adopted
for various types of guarantees to minimize inconsistencies in treatment
across institutions and, if so, views on what methods would best reflect
industry practices. In this regard, the Agencies would be particularly
interested in information on how banking organizations are currently
treating various forms of guarantees within their economic capital
allocation systems and the methods used to adjust PD, LGD, EAD, and any
combination thereof
Page 92 of the ANPR states that "the adjusted risk weight for [a] hedged
obligation could not be less than the risk weight associated with a
comparable direct exposure on the protection provider". While this
application of the "substitution approach" may be roughly appropriate to
certain forms of guarantees in which the financial condition of the
borrower and guarantor are closely linked (say, a proprietor who
provides a personal guarantee against the performance of his business),
there are other forms of guarantees (such as credit derivatives), where
this approach does not adequately recognize the lower risk of joint
default or the benefit of double recovery associated with guarantees.
Failure to recognize the risk mitigation
effect of double default in credit derivatives would send inappropriate
signals to banks about the use of guarantees and credit derivatives --
financial instruments that have provided enormous value in the active
management of portfolio credit risk.
As one illustration of the proposal's
inadequacy, consider the case where a AA-rated counterparty is used to
enact a hedge on an unrelated AA-rated exposure in the banking book.
Using the substitution approach, there would be no capital benefit.
Moreover, the bank would have to add a capital charge for the
counterparty exposure associated with the hedge provider. In effect, the
bank would be required to hold more capital than if it had not hedged at
all.
As a solution to this situation, we would
support the use of some form of the modified ASRF approach suggested in
the recent Federal Reserve paper on guarantees and credit derivatives.
Under this approach, regulators could (at least initially) assign the
necessary 3 "types" of asset value correlation (AVC) in conservative
fashion (e.g., obligor and guarantor AVCs according to the Basel AVC-PD
equation for commercial credits, and a "wrong-way"
asset-value-correlation of, say, 50%). This would produce significant
reductions in the regulatory capital charges for a hedged transaction.
Question # 25 p. 96
Additional requirements for recognized
credit derivatives
The Agencies invite comment on this
issue, as well as consideration of an alternative approach whereby the
notional amount of a credit derivative that does not include
restructuring as a credit event would be discounted. Comment is sought
on the appropriate level of discount and whether the level of discount should vary on the basis offor example,
whether the underlying obligor has publicly outstanding rated debt or
whether the underlying is an entity whose obligations have a relatively high
likelihood of restructuring relative to default (for example, a
sovereign or PSE). Another alternative that commenters may wish to
discuss is elimination of the restructuring requirement for credit
derivatives with a maturity that is considerably longer --for example,
two years --than that of the hedged obligation.
We agree with the position in CP3 that
restructuring does not need to be included as a credit event in a credit
derivative contract, provided the bank has control over the decision to
restructure. At the same time, a contract with restructuring can provide
greater credit risk coverage than one without it. Thus, the
restructuring discount approach could be an attractive option. However,
no restructuring discount should be implemented until a reasonable
amount of credit protection has been recognized by the new Accord in the
first place. Placing a discount on top of the meager benefit granted by
the substitution approach would effectively eliminate the benefit of the
credit hedge altogether.
We support ISDA's proposed methodology
for determining the discount factor.
Question #26 p.96
Additional requirements for recognized
credit derivatives con't.
Comment is sought on this matter, as well
as on the possible alternative treatment of recognizing the hedge in
these two cases for regulatory capital purposes but requiring that
mark-to-market gains on the credit derivative that have been taken into income be deducted from Tier 1
capital.
Supervisors are worried that banks may
recognize too much regulatory capital as a result of the inconsistent
treatment for a loan with accrual accounting versus its credit default
swap (CDS) hedge with MTM accounting. We acknowledge the existence of an
accounting asymmetry. However, we do not believe that regulators should
attempt to solve what is essentially a FAS133 problem within the Basel
II framework. Indeed, there are other significant instances in which
GAAP policy differs from or is not based on best-practice risk
measurement. Further, even if GAAP were to move to a purely MTM
framework, such a framework would still not be always appropriate from a
risk measurement perspective. For example, for a loan whose spread is
risk related, a decline in credit quality (increase in risk rating) may
result in little or no decline in market value (due to the contractual
increase in margin), but additional economic capital should be assigned
to the credit. In the case of MTM hedges coupled with accrual accounting
loans, the right approach is to fix U.S. general accounting principals.
If Basel were to enact this proposal then
virtually no capital benefit could be given to credit hedging utilizing
CDS transactions, and the regulatory rule would be sending a very
inappropriate signal to bank risk managers. Further, strictly from a
safety and soundness perspective, we do not believe that there is a
significant regulatory capital advantage being granted by the accounting
asymmetry. That is, suppose the alternative U.S. proposal (embodied in
the question on P. 61 of the ANPR) is not enacted. Then, when hedging a
loan in the banking book with a CDS transaction in the trading account,
additional regulatory capital may be needed for market risk, plus
counterparty risk, in the trading book -- acting to offset the reduction
in capital for the loan in the banking book. It is quite possible that
the result will be higher regulatory capital than before the hedge (even
though internal EC will uniformly decrease with a properly structured
hedge).
For higher quality reference names, in
which a VaR model may be used to estimate market risk capital, the
initial saving on the regulatory capital against the underlying loan
will not be fully offset by the increase in market risk and counterparty
risk capital - which is as it should be, since the hedged loan is safer
than the unhedged loan. After booking the hedge, if the credit quality
of the reference name decreases, there will be a MTM gain in the trading
book (and a corresponding gain in Tier 1 capital) - but this gain will
be offset by a) an increase in counterparty risk capital since the CDS
is more in-the-money, b) an increase in market risk capital due to an
increase in VaR, and c) a possible increase in the ALLL due to a
reassessment of the underlying credit's quality (even if there is no
change in specific reserves, a lower risk rating would imply a higher
estimated EL and thus an addition to the ALLL under current accounting
practices). Thus, the alternative U.S. proposal - which would subtract
the MTM gains on the derivative from Tier 1 capital - should not be
implemented. Any regulatory capital asymmetries (which, in any event,
are not matched by internal EC asymmetries) would best be eliminated
through a MTM accounting treatment of the loan/hedge package.
Question # 27 p.98
Treatment of maturity mismatch
The Agencies have concerns that the
proposed formulation does not appropriately reflect distinctions between
bullet and amortizing underlying obligations. Comment is sought on the
best way of making such a distinction, as well as more generally on
alternative methods for dealing with the reduced credit risk coverage
that results from a maturity mismatch.
The essential problem with the Agencies
view with regard to credit risk mitigation is that it is
transaction-oriented, rather than exhibiting a portfolio perspective.
Wells Fargo would address a counterparty hedging exercise by creating a
credit exposure profile over time for the counterparty, with netting of
all exposures to this name across the bank. Thus, the hedge profiles
would be netted against the profiles of the underlying exposures, with
any residual exposures converted into bullet loan equivalents and
charged for internal EC. Additional EC would be assigned for credit
derivatives that do not function as explicit guarantees (i.e., credit
derivatives involving basis risk).
Under the ANPR proposal, it appears that
banks would have to match each hedge to a particular underlying
transaction. Thus, two completely offsetting (but individually
mismatched) trades, rather than having a net capital allocation of zero,
would have positive capital assigned to each "paired" trade.
Furthermore, maturity mismatches would be treated on a transaction-bytransaction
basis. Even worse, under the proposal a three-year hedge of a 5-year
loan would receive only 60% of the benefit of a five-year hedge and, in
the next year, the two-year hedge of the (remaining) 4-year loan would
receive only 50% of the benefit of a matched maturity hedge. There would
be no capital saving at all for a one-year remaining life hedge. This
treatment is far more conservative than implied by the maturity
adjustments embedded in the regulatory ASRF model itself.
This arbitrary treatment should be
replaced by simply accounting for maturity mismatches as the difference
between AIRB capital on the underlying (given its maturity) and the AIRB
capital on the hedge (given its maturity). The bank would also have to
hold capital for the counterparty exposure associated with the hedge
provider.
Question #28 p. 99
Treatment of counterparty risk for credit
derivative contracts
The Agencies are seeking industry views
on the PFE add-ons proposed above and their applicability. Comment is
also sought on whether different add-ons should apply for different
remaining maturity buckets for credit derivatives and, if so, views on the appropriate percentage
amounts for the add-ons in each bucket.
No specific comment.
Question #29 p. 102
Equity Exposures - Positions covered
The Agencies encourage comment on whether
the definition of an equity exposure is sufficiently clear to allow
banking organizations to make an appropriate determination as to the
characterization of their assets.
No specific comment.
Question # 30 p. 103
Equity Exposures - Zero and low risk
investments
Comment is sought on whether other types
of equity investments in PSEs should be exempted from the capital charge
on equity exposures, and if so, the appropriate criteria for determining
which PSEs would be exempted.
No specific comment.
Question #31 p. 104
Equity Exposures: Nationally legislated
programs
The Agencies seek comment on what
conditions might be appropriate for this partial exclusion from the A-IRB
equity capital charge. Such conditions could include limitations on the
size and types of businesses in which the banking organization invests,
geographical limitations, or maximum limitations on the size of
individual investments.
The proposed materiality threshold
designed to assess risk exposure for banks' higher risk equity holdings
is 10% of Tier 1 plus Tier 2 capital. At a 10% Total Capital level, this
is equivalent to a 1 % of assets test. This seems like a very low
materiality threshold - perhaps 3% or 5% of total assets might be more
reasonable. In conjunction with this modification, we would recommend
that certain lower-risk equity investments, such as CRA investments, be discounted when included in the
materiality calculation.
Question #32 p. 104-105
Equity Exposures: Nationally legislated
programs Con't.
The Agencies seek comment on whether any
conditions relating to the exclusion of CEDE investments from the A-IRB
equity capital charge would be appropriate. These conditions could serve
to limit the exclusion to investments in CEDEs that meet specific public
welfare goals or to limit the amount of CEDE investments that would
qualms for the exclusion from the A-IRB equity capital charge. The
Agencies also seek comment on whether any other classes of legislated
pro gram equity exposures should be excluded from the A-IRB equity
capital charge.
No specific comment.
Question # 33 p. 109
Equity Exposures: Grandfathered
Investments - Description of quantitative principles
Comment is specifically sought on whether
the measure of an equity exposure under AFS accounting continues to be
appropriate or whether a different rule for the inclusion of revaluation
gains should be adopted.
No specific comment.
Question #34 p. 115-116
Supervisory Assessment of A-IRB
Framework: US Supervisory Review
The Agencies seek comment on the extent
to which an appropriate balance has been struck between flexibility and
comparability for the A-IRB requirements. If this balance is not appropriate, what are
the specific areas of imbalance, and what is the potential impact of the
identified imbalance? Are there alternatives that would provide greater
flexibility, while meeting the overall objective of producing accurate and consistent
ratings?
The Agencies also seek comment on the
supervisory standards contained in the draft guidance. Do the standards
cover all of the key elements of an A-IRB framework? Are there specific practices
that appear to meet the objectives of accurate and consistent ratings
but that would be ruled out by the supervisory standards related to controls and
oversight? Are there particular elements from the corporate guidance
that should be modified or reconsidered as the Agencies draft guidance
for other types of credit?
In addition, the Agencies seek comment on
the extent to which these proposed requirements are consistent with the
ongoing improvements banking organizations are making in credit-risk
management processes.
There has been a relatively uniform set
of concerns communicated to the Basel Committee in response to
Consultative Paper 3 (CP3) on the topic of prescriptiveness. However, we
fear that these criticisms have been too general in nature to be of much
value as an agent of change. In fact, the Committee may be receiving
mixed signals from the industry in terms of its requests to have more
rigidity built into the Accord on some issues and less rigidity on
others.
The areas where we feel that clarity is
required relate primarily to definitional issues within the Accord - a
common definition of default or future margin income, long-run average
versus point in time PD or LGD estimates, and similar metrics or terms
that are necessary to create an unambiguous foundation upon which the
new, more risk-sensitive, regulatory capital calculations can be
computed.
Where clarity is not required, and where
the Supervisory Guidance steps over the line and into the realm of
unwarranted prescriptiveness, comes from its attempts to dictate how
banks actually manage risk. The Supervisory Guidance is too prescriptive
and inflexible in its vision of the risk management processes to which
banks must adhere.
This is in stark contrast to the original
supposition of Basel II -- that each bank would be allowed to continue
the use of its existing risk management practices, so long as they could
be shown to have been effective over time. The Accord and Supervisory
Guidance should only aspire to establish a more risk-sensitive framework
for constructing minimum bank regulatory capital requirements. They
cannot, and should not, attempt to dictate how banks actually manage
risk. For those institutions, such as Wells Fargo, with proven risk
management processes in place, it would be imprudent, and perhaps
dangerous, for them to make significant changes to their risk management
systems in the absence of quantifiable and validated data that clearly
demonstrates that an alternate system is more robust and accurate, and
could be successfully inculcated into their risk management process.
Please refer to our separate letter on
the Draft Supervisory Guidance on Internal Ratings-Based Systems for
Corporate Credit for more specific comments on the supervisory standards
for AIRB.
Question #35 p. 118
Securitization - Operational Criteria
The Agencies seek comment on the proposed
operational requirements for securitizations. Are the proposed criteria
for risk transference and clean-up calls consistent with existing market
practices?
Banks should be permitted to exercise a
clean-up call when the securitization exposures fall below 10% of either
(i) the original principal amount of exposures issued or (ii) the
original pool balance of all assets acquired to support such exposures.
The purpose of the clean-up call is administrative convenience when the
size of a transaction no longer justifies the servicing costs. We
believe that, if appropriately exercised so as to not be implicit
support, whether the 10% is based on the size of the pool or the size of
the remaining balance of exposures should be irrelevant. We note that
many clean-up calls are currently based on the size of the issued
exposures and would have to be unnecessarily amended (which can be time
consuming and costly in the term market) if our comment were not taken.
Question #36 p. 122
Securitization - Maximum Capital
requirement
Comments are invited on the circumstances
under which the retention of the treatment in the general risk-based
capital rules for residual interests for banking organizations using the A-IRB approach to
securitization would be appropriate.
Should the Agencies require originators
to hold dollar-for-dollar capital against all retained securitization
exposures, even if this treatment would result in an aggregate amount of
capital required of the originator that exceeded KIRB plus any applicable deductions? Please provide
the underlying rationale.
We support the currently contemplated cap
on required capital for retained positions of an originator at the KIRB
of the underlying pool as if it had not been securitized. Assuming that
the KIRB of the underlying exposures is appropriately calibrated, it is
inappropriate to hold more capital for a part of that risk as opposed to
the entirety of that risk. Without the cap, total capitalization after a
securitization could be multiples of capital prior to a securitization,
a result that further evidences the miscalibration of the RBA and SFA
for securitizations. We further advocate the ability to use assigned
ratings to override positions within KIRB that have true credit
protection, either through the tranching of the KIRB exposure or through
the presence of credit risk mitigants not recognized in the SFA. We do
not believe that the presence of one of these features should preclude
the presence of the other. They address separate issues that should be
separately considered on their merits.
Question #37 p. 125-126
Securitization -
Positions below KIRB
The Agencies seek comment on the proposed
treatment of securitization exposures held by originators. In
particular, the Agencies seek comment on whether originating banking
organizations should be permitted to calculate A-IRB capital charges for
securitizations exposures below the KIRB threshold based on an external or inferred rating, when
available.
We believe that originators should not be
treated differently than investing institutions with respect to the
capital treatment of retained or repurchased tranches of
securitizations. Rather than being required to deduct from
regulatory capital all positions below KIRB regardless of rating,
originators should be allowed to apply the same RBA risk weights used by
investors for the subject tranches when performing the calculation,
since the risk is the same.
Question #38 p. 126
Securitization - Positions above KIRB
The Agencies seek comment on whether
deduction should be required for all nonrated positions above KIRB. What
are the advantages and disadvantages of the SFA approach versus the
deduction approach?
No specific comment.
Question #39 p. 130
Securitization - Ratinqs Based Approach (RBA)
The Agencies seek comment on the proposed
treatment of securitization exposures under the RBA. For rated
securitization exposures, is it appropriate to differentiate risk weights based on
tranche thickness and pool granularity?
For non-retail securitizations, will
investors generally have sufficient information to calculate the
effective number of underlying exposures (N)?
What are views on the thresholds, based
on N and Q, for determining when the different risk weights apply in the
RBA?
Are there concerns regarding the
reliability of external ratings and their use in determining regulatory
capital? How might the Agencies address any such potential concerns?
Unlike the A-IRB framework for wholesale
exposures, there is no maturity adjustment within the proposed RBA. Is
this reasonable in light of the criteria to assign external ratings?
We believe that the proposed risk weights
in the Ratings-Based Approach to be used by Investing Banks in the
mezzanine and senior tranches of securitizations are too high, and could
lead to irrational incentives to trade securities. These weights could
be made to coincide more closely with the weights generated by the
corporate risk weight formula for assets with comparable PD's.
We believe that it is important that the
RBA be recalculated using the Perraudin and Peretyatkin model, but
changing the key LGD assumption previously used for calibrating risk
weights for granular highly rated tranches that qualify for risk weights
calculated in column 1 of the RBA table. While the ideal would be
different assumptions for different asset classes, we believe an
appropriate LGD assumption that is workable across the board for these
thick, granular positions is one between 5% and 10%, rather than the 50%
LGD assumption that underlies the current RBA factors.
Question #40 p. 137
Securitization - Supervisory formula
approach (SFA)
The Agencies seek comment on the proposed
SFA. How might it be simplified without sacrificing significant risk
sensitivity? How useful are the alternative simplified computation
methodologies for N and LGD?
i. The floor capital charge is too high
With respect to liquidity and credit
enhancement positions for Asset-Backed Commercial Paper conduits, we
suggest that, rather than a floor for each transaction, the floor
capital requirement under the SFA should be a floor for an overall
portfolio. First, a portfolio-wide floor gives a bank continued
incentive to continue to structure highly rated, very safe transactions
on a transactionby-transaction basis. Under the proposed deal by deal
floor, there will be little incentive to structure tranches to ratings
levels beyond which the floor overrides the actual risk of a position.
Second, recognizing that any floor is arbitrary, a portfolio-wide floor
imposes only one conservative assumption rather than the multiple
conservative assumptions in a deal by deal analysis. We believe a
portfolio-wide floor significantly reduces the distortions that are
inevitable when any arbitrary floor is imposed but continues to provide
a means for regulators to maintain an appropriately conservative minimum
regulatory capital requirement.
If the Agencies were not to accept a
portfolio-wide floor, we believe that the current floor proposal is so
high as to cause great distortions between what are meant to be minimum
capital requirements and economic capital held by a bank.
ii. Additional Credit for Future Margin
Income
In the U.S. Proposal, the Agencies have
recognized and given partial credit to the sizing of revolving retail
asset securitizations to create an expected level of future margin
income being available to cover expected losses on the portfolio. We
note that securitizations of other interest-bearing assets have the same
structure and expectation of available future margin income as retail
exposures.
We believe the Agencies should give
credit to all asset classes where the yield on the assets is used to
cover expected losses. In securitizations with future margin income,
transaction structures may differ significantly and in some cases the
financing institution would not be entitled to any of the excess spread
on the portfolio (for example in cases where the excess spread is
returned to the seller of the receivable pool). Only that portion of the
future margin income, if any, that exceeds ongoing transaction expenses
(i.e., the excess spread) should be given credit as credit enhancement.
We also believe the Agencies should
expand the credit given for the existence of future margin income to all
transaction types structured to allow for excess yield (future margin
income that exceeds ongoing transaction expenses) on assets to serve as
credit enhancement to cover expected losses. We note that rating agency
methodology, the cornerstone of the RBA, gives credit for the existence
of such credit-enhancing excess spread structures. In fact, many times
in transactions where excess spread is used to provide protection
against losses, the second form of loss protection (e.g.,
overcollateralization) will be required to be sized much smaller than it
would otherwise need to be in order to cover losses. For the SFA to
accurately assess the risks of these transactions and provide
consistency between the RBA approach and the SFA, the SFA must recognize
this form of credit enhancement in all transactions where it exists.
iii. More Appropriate Treatment for
Dilution Risk
The U.S. Proposal treats dilution risk
extremely conservatively. The current proposal does not give any credit
to contractual recourse to the seller for dilution in asset types such
as trade receivables and credit card receivables where dilution risk is
relevant. This is contrary to rating agency and industry practice that
acknowledges that contractual recourse for dilution is the risk
equivalent of an unsecured loan to the seller of the receivables. The
U.S. Proposal dictates that when calculating capital for asset pools
that have dilution risk, there is a requirement to use the expected loss
from dilution as the PD and 100% for LGD, which results in a grossly
overstated KIRB.
The 100% LGD assumed in the U.S. Proposal
for calculating dilution risk under the SFA is inappropriate. First,
dilution risk, unlike most forms of credit risk, is not only mitigated
by the presence of recourse to the seller of receivables to cover
dilution losses but also, in many cases, by reserves sized as a multiple
of expected losses to cover both EL and UL. This seller recourse is a
meaningful and material risk mitigation tool and should be acknowledged
as equivalent risk of an unsecured loan.
iv. More Appropriate Parameters for LGD
To apply the top down approach a bank
must decompose expected loss ("EL") into its probability of default
("PD") and loss given default ("LGD") components. If these numbers
cannot be derived in a "reliable" manner, extremely conservative proxies
of PD and 100% LGD and EAD assumptions must be applied. It is likely
that banKs relying on the top down approach would be required to use
these conservative assumptions. We suggest that a revised top down
approach provide a table of LGD parameters for securitizations rather
than an LGD being equal to 100%. We suggest that this table be
delineated by asset class.
Question #41 p.138-139
Securitization - The look-through
approach for eligible liquidity facilities
The Agencies seek comment on the proposed
treatment of eligible liquidity facilities, including the qualifying
criteria for such facilities. Does the proposed Look-Through Approach -- to be available
as a temporary measure -satisfactorily address concerns that, in some
cases, it may be impractical for providers of liquidity facilities to
apply either the "bottom-up" or "top-down" approach for calculating K[RB?
It would be helpful to understand the degree to which any potential
obstacles are likely to persist.
Feedback also is sought on whether
liquidity providers should be permitted to calculate A-IRB capital
charges based on their internal risk ratings for such facilities in
combination with the appropriate RBA risk weight. What are the
advantages and disadvantages of such an approach, and how might the
Agencies address concerns that the supervisory
validation of such internal ratings would be difficult and burdensome?
Under such an approach, would the lack of any maturity adjustment with
the RBA be problematic for assigning reasonable risk weights to liquidity facilities backed by
relatively short-term receivables, such as trade credit?
Under the proposed Look-Through Approach,
the risk weight applicable to unrated liquidity positions is the highest
risk weight assigned to any of the underlying exposures covered by that
position. We believe that the more appropriate measure is to look to the
weighted average of the risk weights. This weighted average risk would
reflect the true risks in the portfolio as opposed to an overly
conservative estimation of the risks reflected by an assumption that the
highest risk asset (regardless of size) is a valid estimate for the risk
in the entire portfolio.
Question #42 p. 139
Securitization - Other Considerations -
Capital treatment absent an A-IRBA Approach - the Alternative RBA
Should the A-IRB capital treatment for
securitization exposures that do not have a specific A-IRB treatment be
the same for investors and originators? If so, which treatment should be applied - that used
for investors (the RBA) or originators (the Alternative RBA)? The
rationale for the response would be helpful.
We do not believe that an Alternate RBA
Approach is appropriate for those asset classes for which an A-IRB
Approach is unavailable to a bank. So long as a position has been rated,
the bank should be permitted to use the RBA Approach regardless of
whether it is an originator or an investor. We anticipate that it will
be the exception rather than the rule that an A-IRB Approach will be
unavailable to a bank for a particular asset class for the banks
expected to be covered by the A-IRB in the U.S. In these limited
circumstances, we believe that regulatory review and monitoring of the
development of a particular A-IRB is more appropriate than requiring
potentially distortive capital treatment for a position.
Question #43 p. 143
Securitization - Determination of CCFs
for non-controlled early amortization structures
The Agencies seek comment on the proposed
treatment of securitization of revolving credit facilities containing
early amortization mechanisms. Does the proposal satisfactorily address the
potential risks such transactions pose to originators?
Comments are invited on the interplay
between the A-IRB capital charge for securitization structures
containing early amortization features and that for undrawn lines that
have not been securitized. Are there common elements that the Agencies should consider? Specific
examples would be helpful.
Are proposed differences in CCFs for
controlled and non-controlled amortization mechanisms appropriate? Are
there other factors that the Agencies should consider?
We support the Agencies' proposal
recognizing early amortization risks and their associated capital
requirements will vary based on both the asset type and the nature of
the early amortization provisions. Nevertheless, there are a number of
needed changes to the qualification conditions for controlled early
amortization treatment. First, the U.S. Proposal should be clear that
the amortization requirements would apply only to economic pay-out
events and not normal amortization or accumulation periods. The early
amortization capital charge represents a new capital requirement
specifically targeting the credit and liquidity risks associated with
early amortization events - when things go bad. As a result, the
amortization requirements should only apply to the specific economic
early amortization risk. During normal amortization periods, the loans,
by definition, are performing well and liquidity requirements are
incorporated into the bank's liquidity planning process.
Second, we believe that the requirements
for when an amortization provision is considered "controlled" are too
restrictive by requiring that there be a pro rata sharing of interest,
principal, expenses, losses and recoveries based on the balance of
receivables outstanding at the beginning of the month. We believe the
two other requirements set forth for "controlled" amortization
provisions clearly establish the fundamental principles for these
amortization. Namely, they state that 1) the amortization period be
sufficiently long so that 90% of the debt outstanding at the beginning
of the amortization period is repaid or recognized as in default and 2)
amortization occurs at a pace no more rapid than straight-line
amortization. We believe that the U.S. Proposal should clearly
articulate a guiding principle as it has done with the two provisions
referred to in the preceding sentence, and not micro-manage the rules.
Therefore, we believe the pro rata sharing requirement should be deleted
in its entirety.
Third, we note that while the proposed
amortization rules make sense in the credit card context, it is not
clear that the same application should be used across the board for
other revolving retail assets. For example, some securitizations early
amortization provisions are linked to the size of the
overcollateralization in a transaction. Therefore, the appropriate
triggers in those securitizations should be to the level of
overcollateralization rather than the level of excess spread. The final
rules for amortization provisions should provide regulators with
sufficient flexibility to apply appropriate modifications to the
amortization rules when the context requires.
Question #44 p.145
Securitization - Servicer cash advances
When providing servicer cash advances,
are banking organizations obligated to advance funds up to a specified
recoverable amount? If so, does the practice differ by asset type?
Please provide a rationale for the response given.
No specific comment.
Question #45 p. 147
AMA Framework for Operational Risk
The Agencies are proposing the AMA to
address operational risk for regulatory cap ital purposes. The Agencies
are interested, however, in possible alternatives. Are there alternative concepts or
approaches that might be equally or more effective in addressing
operational risk? If so, please provide some discussion on possible alternatives.
Certain operational loss events are
relatively small and frequent. Such events can be successfully modeled
through the use of statistical techniques applied to historical data
sets. Because such losses are relatively predictable, they can
effectively be priced into the product, in much the same manner as
expected credit losses are priced into credit products, and we support
the Committee's decision to allow Future Margin Income to offset the
expected component of such losses.
However, we are doubtful that similar
statistical techniques can be applied to historical data to reliably
model extreme, operational loss events. Truly catastrophic loss events
cannot be predicted, and no amount of capital will protect an
institution in such an instance. We believe that some form of
qualitative (scenario analysis) modeling is more appropriate in
assessing those types of loss events that are less predictable.
Accordingly, we think that more development is necessary to finalize
exactly what types of loss events ought, realistically, to be captured
under AMA approaches to Operational Risk capital formulations.
The proposed AMA framework for
Operational Risk leaves banks with the task of developing a complex and
costly methodology for operational loss estimation. This choice begs the
question of whether there may be an alternative approach that
demonstrates that no capital is required for operational risk, given a
particular bank's facts and circumstances, or whether there are
alternative approaches to determining operational risk capital that are
consistent with the way sound businesses actually operate, without being
overly complex or costly to administer.
For example, we note that the well-known
concept of operating leverage, or business risk, seems to be totally
overlooked in the Basel Committee's operational risk capital
deliberations. We feel that constructing a business-based approach to
operational risk capital should be viewed as an acceptable alternative
to the AMA track. We would encourage further discussions between the
regulatory agencies and their regulated institutions along the lines of
quantifying the main elements, definitions, and procedures of this type
of framework.
Because there is no accepted methodology
for quantifying Operational Risk, we believe that the AMA approach
should not be the only option made available to U.S. banks. All
institutions subject to the Accord should be allowed to develop any risk
measurement methodology (Basic Indicator, Standard, AMA, or an
alternative such as a business-based approach) that is acceptable to
their national banking supervisors, and to disclose their methodology
and their key controls for managing operational risk in their public
filings.
Question #46 p. 152 AMA Capital
Calculation
Does the broad structure that the
Agencies have outlined incorporate all the key elements that should be
factored into the operational risk framework for regulatory capital? If not, what other
issues should be addressed? Are any elements included not directly
relevant for operational risk measurement or management? The Agencies have not
included indirect losses (for example, opportunity costs) in the
definition of operational risk against which institutions would have to
hold capital; because such losses can be substantial, should they be included in the definition of
operational risk?
Wells Fargo has a basic difference of
opinion with the Basel Committee with respect to the capital treatment
of Operational Risk, insofar as we don't believe that capital should be
required for Operational Risk at all. To understand this perspective,
one must first bifurcate operational losses into two segments -- 1) high
frequency/low severity losses that can be statistically assessed,
expensed, and priced for, and 2) low frequency/high severity losses that
cannot be reliably modeled.
We would argue that high severity losses
should be outside the scope of a formulaic approach to minimum
regulatory capital standards, because they are unpredictable and so
remote as to be outside the statistical bounds of what should be
captured in capital at risk formulae. We also feel that the more
predictable forms of operational losses are 1) simply a cost of doing
business to a bank and, therefore, routinely factored into the way that
banking products are priced, 2) quite stable over time, because of their
predictability and absence of correlation across businesses, and 3)
likely to be entirely offset by the Future Margin Income generated by a
bank in aggregate, across all of its operational businesses. Many of
these losses are either expensed or accrued for by banks. Because the
Advanced Measurement Approach (AMA) would allow for the recognition of
imperfect correlation of risks and the impact of Future Margin Income,
we feel that the aggregate outcome of such modeling of predictable
operational losses would typically result in a zero capital requirement,
and thus, such risks should simply be exempted from the minimum
regulatory capital requirements in the first place, as they are today.
Notwithstanding this point of view, we
have considered some of the questions on operational risk posed by the
ANPR. With respect to the scope of operational losses addressed by the
Accord, the ANPR defines operational risk to include "...exposure to
litigation from all aspects of an institution's activities." This would
appear to include settlements of baseless lawsuits as operational risk
losses. In many cases, these settlements are made to control costs or to
maintain customer relations and more appropriately represent strategic
risk rather than operational risk. We believe that this language should
be modified, so that banks would have some flexibility to exclude
certain lawsuit settlements from the scope of operational risk capital.
We do not believe that the direct
incorporation of external loss data should be a required component of a
bank's operational loss modeling. While it is instructive for banks to
be aware of external loss events, applying that information across all
institutions in a formulaic manner seems problematic to us. The quality
and consistency of external data would prove difficult to verify,
especially given the lack of common data collection standards within the
industry. Furthermore, each bank will have its own inherent and specific
causes of risk depending on the diversification of its lines of business
and appetite for risk. Without a relatively detailed awareness of the
internal control conditions that led to those losses at other
institutions, it is difficult, at best, to do much more than guess the
impact of a seemingly similar event on a given bank. Accordingly,
external data should only be one of several, optional considerations
when performing scenario analysis, and not necessarily the most
important.
Question #47 p. 149
AMA - Overview of Supervisory Criteria
The Agencies seek comment on the extent
to which an appropriate balance has been struck between flexibility and
comparability for the operational risk requirement. If this balance is not
appropriate, what are the specific areas of imbalance and what is the
potential impact of the identified imbalance?
The Agencies are considering additional
measures to facilitate consistency in both the supervisory assessment of
AMA frameworks and the enforcement of AIVL4 standards across institutions.
Specifically, the Agencies are considering enhancements to existing
interagency operational and managerial standards to directly address operational risk and to
articulate supervisory expectations for AMA frameworks. The Agencies
seek comment on the need for and effectiveness of these additional
measures.
The Agencies also seek comment on the
supervisory standards. Do the standards cover the key elements of an
operational risk framework?
At Wells Fargo, we believe that we have
consciously crafted a distinct competitive advantage by virtue of the
diversity of our underlying businesses. Between mortgage banking,
commercial banking, insurance, retail deposit taking, and asset
management services (to name a few of our over 80 businesses), along
with the significant economies of scale that we have in each of these
businesses, we feel that Wells Fargo has created a portfolio of risks
(both credit and non-credit) whose worst-case loss potential is
substantially less than the sum of its parts. We are encouraged to see
that the capture of the capital benefits created by business
diversification is permissible under the AMA modeling of operational
risk. We believe that this logic should extend to the modeling of
capital for credit risk as well, where the impact of portfolio
diversification is more substantive and more empirically justifiable.
However, we are concerned by the language
of the ANPR, which states that "Under a bottomup approach, explicit
assumptions regarding cross-event dependence are required to estimate
operational risk exposure at the firm-wide level. Management must
demonstrate that these assumptions are appropriate and reflect the
institution's current environment". The requirement for institutions to
demonstrate that explicit and embedded dependence (correlation)
assumptions are appropriate needs to be clarified. It is important that
reasonability be incorporated into this standard. Insufficient data will
be available to statistically prove correlations across business lines
and event types. Therefore, correlations most likely will be determined
from qualitative reasoning based on the underlying nature of the risks.
We suggest that the language in this section recognize the fact that
qualitative judgment will be necessary and that flexible approaches need
to be allowed, provided that institutions have a well - reasoned basis
for their assumptions. It is important that overly conservative criteria
not be applied regarding correlation assumptions so that banks using
more risk-sensitive "bottoms-up" approaches to the quantification of
operational risk capital are not penalized.
Please refer to our separate letter on
the Draft Supervisory Guidance on Operational Risk Advanced Measurement
Approaches for Regulatory Capital for more specific comments on the
supervisory standards for the AMA.
Question #48 p. 156
AMA-Corporate
Governance
The Agencies are introducing the concept
of an operational risk management function, while emphasizing the
importance of the roles played by the board, management, lines of business, and audit.
Are the responsibilities delineated for each of these functions
sufficiently clear and would they result in a satisfactory process for
managing the operational risk framework?
The ANPR appears to mandate that an
independent, firm-wide operational risk management function exist, which
is separate from line of business management oversight. We believe that
such a directive is premature, given that a consistent, well-meaning
definition of what operational risk comprises does not yet exist. Under
these conditions, how can there be a central committee to oversee
something that is not defined?
For similar reasons, we are concerned
that banking supervisors may interpret the ANPR to develop unrealistic
expectations for the board of directors' involvement in the oversight of
operational risk management. Page 151 of the ANPR states that "the board
of directors would have to oversee the development of the firm-wide
operational risk framework, as well as major changes to the framework
... The board and management would have to ensure that appropriate
resources have been allocated to support the operational risk
framework." It is difficult to require board of directors oversight for
something that is not well defined.
Rather than trying to devise a "one size
fits all" central oversight function for operational risk management, we
think that the Supervisory Guidance should be re-worded to simply
require that there be a thorough governance process for overseeing what
may be multiple types of operational risks, with the details left to the
discretion of individual banks.
Question #49 p. 159
Elements of an AMA Framework
The Agencies seek comment on the
reasonableness of the criteria for recognition of risk mitigants in
reducing an institution - operational risk exposure. In particular, do
the criteria allow for recognition of common insurance policies? If not,
what criteria are most binding against current insurance products? Other
than insurance, are there additional risk mitigation products that
should be considered for operational risk?
To the extent that extreme operational
loss event modeling is deemed realistic, we see no reason why the
recognition of insurance mitigation should be limited to 20% of the
total operational risk capital charge, as suggested by Paragraph 66 of
the Supervisory Guidance. To do so might lead to imprudent risk
management incentives in the use of insurance programs. We recommend
that the capital adjustment for insurance be based on the full amount of
insurance protection provided by insurance policies, given that the
policies meet the qualitative standards outlined in the ANPR.
Question #50 p. 164
Disclosure
Requirements
The Agencies seek comment on the
feasibility of such an approach to the disclosure ofpertinent
information and also whether commenters have any other suggestions
regarding how best to present the required disclosures.
Comments are requested on whether the
Agencies' description of the required formal disclosure policy is
adequate, or whether additional guidance would be useful.
Comments are requested regarding whether
any of the information sought by the Agencies to be disclosed raises any
particular concerns regarding the disclosure of proprietary or
confidential information. If a commenter believes certain of the
required information would be proprietary or confidential, the Agencies
seek comment on why that is so and
alternatives that would meet the objectives of the required disclosure.
The Agencies also seek comment regarding the most efficient means for institutions to meet the
disclosure requirements. Specifically, the Agencies are interested in
comments about the feasibility of requiring institutions to provide all requested information in
one location and also whether commenters have other suggestions on how
to ensure that the requested information is readily available to
market participants.
Wells Fargo believes that the Accord has
ventured beyond its intended scope in its specification of the
disclosure requirements in Pillar 3. The proposed Accord requires that a
bank make extensive disclosures about its risk profile and risk
management processes. We view the proposed requirements for Pillar 3
disclosure as excessive and costly to implement, with the resulting
information being potentially confusing to the investment community,
particularly with respect to efforts to compare the risk profile of one
institution to another. Rather, we feel that market forces can act as a
better policing authority for required disclosures, compelling companies
to achieve a requisite level of transparency on topical issues. We
believe that the proposed approach is flawed on several counts:
• First, we see no basic need for such
disclosures. The market is sufficiently well informed already, as
evidenced by the breadth of banks' securities issuance activities.
Securities transactions require the market to constantly assess a
financial institution's creditworthiness, risk profile, and capital
structure. If the market needs more information in order to perform this
assessment, it will demand it; and, it will penalize the reputation of
those that cannot provide the necessary information. We do not believe
that the Basel Committee can effectively, nor should it, determine the
informational requirements of bank credit markets.
• Second, efforts to employ disclosures
such as those proposed in order to make comparisons in the risk profiles
of two financial institutions will invariably lead to misinterpretations
among readers of the information. We know well from our considerable
experience in acquiring other banks how different two banks' approaches
to risk rating loans can be. Without exception, we have come away from
the due diligence efforts on potential acquisition candidates planning
for the changes that we will have to make to the target company's
reporting of its risk profile in order to make it comparable to our more
conservative approach. This same issue will extend to a comparison of
Probability Of Default, Loss Given Default, and other metrics across
institutions, as each company will take a different approach to its
parameter estimation process.
• Third, the Pillar 3 disclosure
requirements may be duplicative to, and potentially inconsistent with,
existing or future GAAP and non-GAAP accounting disclosures, and
unnecessarily costly to compile and report within adequate standards of
audit controls. We view the potential for lawsuits as being very high,
and regard the provisions of Paragraph 765 of CP3 (which allows that
Pillar 3 disclosures need not be audited externally, unless otherwise
required) as an empty gesture, since no large issuer is going to be
disclosing material public information without appropriate (but costly
and time consuming) internal review.
• And fourth, the proposed disclosures
will create an uneven playing field between banks and their non-bank
competitors, who will be free to pursue their business activities
unencumbered by supervisory capital rules and the excessive compliance
costs that they will engender.
We recommend that Pillar 3 be eliminated
or, at least, made voluntary, so that the market and those agencies that
are appropriately tasked with safeguarding the interests of investors
(i.e., the SEC, the FASB, and the rating agencies) could determine the
need for any additional disclosure about a public company's risk profile
and risk management practices.
|